EMPIRICAL LITERATURE OF BUDGET DEFICIT



According to previous findings about the impact of budget deficits on the developing economies, it was found that:

  1. The budget deficits are unambiguously bad for economic growth.
  2. High budget deficits are mostly explained as consequence of planned political decisions and not as consequences of external shocks or reaction on current internal economic situations.
  3.   Although short term budget deficits financing by demonetization doesn’t necessarily lead to inflation, in long term horizon, demonetization causes inflation growth.
  4. There is some evidence that public investments are not always positive investments, which denies the general opinion on the question. The public investments have negative effects on private investments. Public investments replace rather than complement private investment.
  5.   A budget deficit causes current account deficit and overvaluation of the exchange rate. This makes another negative impact on economic growth and also leads to decrease in exports.
  6.   Reducing budget deficits is an effective policy measure in raising national savings.




READ RELATED TOPICS ON DEFICIT BUDGET 

SUMMARY, CONCLUSION AND RECOMMENDATION OF BUDGET DEFICIT
METHODOLOGY OF BUDGET DEFICIT (TECHNIQUES, MODEL, STATISTICAL DATA  THE STANDARD VIEW OF BUDGET DEFICITS IN ECONOMICS

Agu (1988) reviewed IMF journal on the effect of budget deficit on GDP to ascertain the determinants of macroeconomic volatility and its implications on economic growth in Nigeria. He noted the existence of trade imbalance and negative real interest rate during most of the review period (1970-1985). He demonstrated the negative effect of budget deficit on GDP over time using Mckinnon financial repression diagram. His main conclusion was that the relationship between budget deficit and macro economic aggregates is a dual sign that is some are negatively related while some are positively related to fiscal deficit.

            Lansing (2001) evaluates the impact of budget deficit on economic performance. It discusses the theoretical arguments, reviews the international evidence, highlights the latest academic research, cites examples of countries that have significantly improved their share of national economic output, owing to controlled deficits and analysed the economic consequences of these reforms. The conclusion was that fiscal deficit exerts negative relationship with macroeconomic variables like savings through interest rate and hence retards growth.

            Nwodo (2001) analyzed the long-run effect of budget deficit on economic growth of Nigeria for the first half of the 1990s. the main findings was that budget deficit did matter, but only to the extent it contributed to the money growth and of not checked, induces inflation, hence, leading to a distorted economy. As most of the budget imbalance was being monetized during that period, it is no surprise that independent influence of the budget deficit on the GDP growth was not found. 

            The conventional wisdom about deficit crowding our private investment is strongly reaffirmed by the studies conducted by world observers using case studies of 10 countries. According to the observer, the private credit in high deficit financially repressed economies have event worsen effects than the increase in interest rate in high deficits. In unrepressed economies, the quality of investment was empirically confirmed in countries as diverse as Argentine, Cote d’Ivore and Thailand. Further studies conducted that deficits due to high public investment are less harmful. In some countries, the effect of public or private investment is positive; for example, Morocco, Pakistan, Thailand and Zimbabwe, while in countries in Chile, Columbia, Ghana, Mexico, it is negative. However, what matters most is the type of government and investment, if public partially compliments privates’ capital, greater private capital formation is likely.

Dervis and Patri (1993); Borinton, Jones and Kigue (1984); Fisher (1993); Ghura and Grennes (1993); Goldbrough et al (1996); Schmidt-Hebbel (1996); Lenisk K. (1996); Calamistris, B and Ghura (1999); they argued that macroeconomic stability has a variety of internal and external causes, its primary sources throughout Africa and other less developed countries have been persistent public sector deficits financed by money creation which resulted to high and rising inflation, unserviceable level of external debt, stagnant and declining real income, capita; flight, currency substitution and unstable exchange rates.

Arize and Malindretos (2008) try to investigate the relationship between trade deficits and the budget deficit for ten African countries using popular time series methodologies. In determining the casual relationship between the trade deficit and the budget deficit using error-correction model found a bi-directional long-run causality between the budget deficit and the trade deficits. Their result shed light on the nature of the relationship between the trade deficit and the budget deficit in these developing countries and suggest that balancing the budget cannot be expected to reduce the trade deficits; however, what is needed are both fiscal and monetary polices. In addition, the result suggest that government policy actions aimed at reducing trade and budget deficits can generate at best only uncertain results if the initial focus is not placed on policies that attempt to reduce the trade deficits.

According to Omoke and Oruka (2010), who employed Pair Wise Granger causality Test in an attempt to offer evident on the causal long term relationship between budget deficit, money growth and inflation in Nigeria, considering the broadest definition of money supply, found that money supple causes budget deficit which means that the level of money supply in the Nigerian economy will determine whether there has been or there will be budget deficits. Inflation and budget deficit revealed a bilateral or feedback causality proving that the changes that occur in inflation could be explain by its own lag and also the lag values of budget deficit and in the same vein, changes that occur in budget deficits are explained by its lagged values and the lagged values of inflation. The implication of their findings is that both budget deficit and inflation could be caused by money, supply meaning that they are both monetary phenomena and also, inflation is also caused and found to be dependent on the performance of the budget.

According to Ben (2010), larger budget deficit has adverse effect on the economy because it tends to reduce national saving, which in turn reduces domestic investment and increases borrowing from board, besides, a low level of national savings rises inflation and domestic interest rates and crowds’ private sector investment. The reduction in investment in turn affects employment as firms or business reduces their demand for labour and other factor inputs. All of these reduce national output, which in turn lead to trade deficits and balance of payments and reduction in the overall well-being of the people.

Obi and Abu (2009), explains that fiscal deficits and government debt have positive impact on interest rates, but inflation and international trade were found to have negative effect on interest rates. In their study using vector autoregressive model and covering a period of 1985-2006 suggested that deficit financing leads to a huge debt stock and tends to crowd our private sector investment, by reducing the access of investors to adequate funds, thereby raising interest (and/or lending) rates. The rise in interest rate reduces investment demand and output of goods and services. These in turn reduce national income as well as employment rate, and the overall welfare of the people would decline. Thus, government should make efforts to reduce unnecessary spending because experience has shown that a large proportion of government expenditures have been channelled to unproductive ventures. 

Abdul and Naeem (2008) critically analysed short-term effect of budget deficit on money supply, private and public investment and output, balance of payment, international reserves and unemployment. Using an annual data of Pakistan for the period of 1960-2005 and adopting error Correction Mechanism (ECM), the study revealed that short run changes in money supply is positively related to changes in foreign reserves. The short run changes in money demand are positively related to short run changes in income. The short run changes in output is positively related to short run changes in consumption expenditures, private investment, public investment and balance of trade. It is negatively related to short-run changes in real rate of interest. Short-run changes in private and public investment are positively related to short run changes in output. Short run changes in export is positively related to short run changes in output, relative prices of export and exchange rate. Short run changes in import are negatively related to short run change in exchange rate. Short run change in unemployment is negatively related to short run changes in output growth (GDP). Based on their findings, they recommend that long term private and public investment policies can gain better result in economic growth.

Takero, Toshihiro and Hiroki (2002) argues using Japan as a case study, that when the government debt becomes large and political leadership is weak, it would be much difficult to induce all interest groups to cooperate. They found that with larger deadweight loss of lobbying activities, higher existing privileges and higher government debt are made relative to the benchmark case without deadweight loss. Raising taxes cannot necessarily alleviate the fiscal crisis compared with the benchmark case. Its negative income effect is to enlarge group-specific public works and transfers, resulting in a bigger size of government without reducing government deficits much. This is one of the main reasons why fiscal reconstruction was not completed well in Japan. In order to realize successful fiscal reconstruction, therefore, they need the strong political leadership and efficient decision process. This could lead to an interesting international comparison of fiscal stabilization policy in the real world to cope with budget deficits.

Alessandro (1999) studies the effect of a temporary budget deficit which is financed in the international capital market on the exchange rate. He found that the exchange rate depreciates both in the short and in the long run if the government finances the deficit by selling debt denominated in foreign currencies to non-residents. The governments of many small industrial countries have both financed budget deficits in the international market and changed the currency composition of the outstanding debt. In the study, he argued that these debt management policies cannot prevent the real exchange rate from depreciation in the long run, even though, theoretically, governments can temporarily achieve their exchange targets. In practice, however, the size of official external borrowing and intervention that is needed to maintain the exchange rate even for a short period of time may be feasible because countries may be rationed in the international capital market when their external debt grows rapidly and expectations of a long-run depreciation are sufficiently strong.  

Masayab and Ali (2009) examine the relationship between budget deficit and current account deficits in the Philippines using time series data for the period of 1970-2005. They utilized Toda and Yamatoto procedure in order to determine the direction of causality between budget deficit and current account deficits. Their empirical results give further support to the Keynesian view that there is a strong link between budget deficits and current account deficits in the Philippines. The results of Roda and Yamamotos’ causality analysis supported the existence of bi-directional causality between budget deficits and current account in the Philippines.
Therefore, appropriate measures to reduce budget deficits could play an important role in reducing the current account deficits and vice versa. Also, there are other important factors such as improving the terms of trade; coordination of monetary and fiscal polices; a sustained effort to enhance private saving; measures focusing on efficiency improvement as well as the exchange rate, which will complement the budget cut policy.

Mamodouh (2000) analyses the relationship between budget deficit and trade deficit in petroleum economy, by taking the case of Saudi Arabia as an example. Using animal time series data covering the period of 1970-1999, he analyzed the theoretical framework based on the two hypotheses; the Ricardian equivalence neglects any relationship between the two deficits and the Keynesian proposition confirms the existence of a positive relationship between them. Because of the special characters of the petroleum economy, they tried to argue that any of the two hypotheses is not valid in their economy. Considering the important role of oil revenue of the components of trade accounts and the public budget, they expected a positive relationship among budget deficit and trade deficit, but the direction of the causality is reversed, trade deficits causes’ budget deficit. From their findings, if the government would like to reduce trade and budget deficits, the government must begin by reducing trade deficit. Since the trade deficit depends on oil prices, the government has to diversity the sources of national income. Also, when the oil revenue becomes less important in domestic income, the structural economic transformation may reverse the causality direction between the deficits, and the Keynesian proposition will be more valid.

Using a variety of indicators of Central Bank independence in Columbia, Sikken and Haan (1998) found analogous outcomes for a group of 30 developing countries. Basically, they tested whether such independence affect monetization of the deficit. They concluded that there is no relationship between their Central Bank independence and the budget deficit level. Other findings that show fiscal deficit does not contributed significantly to money growth and inflation are reported by Protopapadakis and Siegel (1987) for samples that include developed economies and by De Haan and Zelhort (1990) for developing countries.  

Yaya (2010) employed the Granger-causality test developed by Toda and Yamatoto (1995) using a sample of seven West African countries namely; Benin, Burkian Faso, Cote d’ Ivoire, Mali, Niger, Senegal and Toto. In order to examine the causal relationship between budget deficits and economic growth in these countries and covering a period of 26 years, found out that in three cases, there was no causality between budget deficits and economic growth. The above findings indicate two-way causality in three countries, deficits having adverse effects on growth. Overall, these results give support to the WAEMU budgetary rule aiming at restricting the size of budget deficit as a prerequisite for sustainable growth and real convergence. In four other countries, there was causality evidence between budget deficit and economic growth implying that deficits retard economic growth rate. These findings have two main implications. First, they lend support to the control of budget deficits within the West African Economic and Monetary Union countries and in order to increase domestic savings and finance economic growth. Second, evidence of causality running from economic growth to deficit makes difficult the control of the size of the budget deficit as to depend on the aggregate economic health. In periods of recession, revenues are expected to decrease, generating fiscal imbalance. In periods of expansion, revenues increases that leads to reduction in the size of deficit.

The World Bank (1993) opined that in economies where financial markets are not repressed, higher deficits financed by domestic debt increase real interest rates when external borrowing is not possible. However, if financial markets are integrated with world capital markets, higher domestic borrowing results in international capital inflows and high foreign debt. Thus, the impact on domestic real interest rates will not be much. Moreover, in counties where the financial markets are repressed (that is interest rate control, compulsory public debt placements and controls on external capital flows), given a fixed nominal interest rates fiscal deficits raises inflation resulting in a repressed (even negative) real interest rates.

Jean and Tahsin (2002) explain that the effects of trade openness on budget balance is through is effects on the instability of government. Governments are often resistant to liberalize their trade regimes. Their argument is that the budget situation is really difficult in developing countries and a liberalization program will lead to larger budget deficits.
Finally, it would suffice to mention that Lansing (2010) intimates that budget deficit exerts negative relationship with macroeconomic variables like savings through interest rate and hence retards growth. Also, Nwodo (2001) explain that budget deficit did matter, but only to the extent it contributes to the money growth and if not checked induces inflation, hence, leading to a distorted economy.


READ RELATED TOPICS ON DEFICIT BUDGET 

SUMMARY, CONCLUSION AND RECOMMENDATION OF BUDGET DEFICIT
METHODOLOGY OF BUDGET DEFICIT (TECHNIQUES, MODEL, STATISTICAL DATA  
 
Share on Google Plus

Declaimer - Unknown

The publications and/or documents on this website are provided for general information purposes only. Your use of any of these sample documents is subjected to your own decision NB: Join our Social Media Network on Google Plus | Facebook | Twitter | Linkedin

READ RECENT UPDATES HERE