DETERMINANTS OF AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTIVITY



Agricultural productivity change is explained by many factors. According to Hussain and Perera, (2004) these factors include: Land and water related factors (such as farm/water course location, quality of land, sources of water, quality and quantity of water and timing of water application, etc.), Climatic factors (i.e. rainfall, temperature, sunshine, frost, etc.), Agronomic factors such as quality, quantity and timing of input application (i.e. seeds, fertilizers, herbicides, labour, etc.), Socio-economic factors (such as farmers’ health, education, experience in farming, farm size, tenancy terms, land fragmentation and availability of credit), Farm management factors (i.e. adoption of modern production technologies, farm planning and management practices, etc.).


         Some of these factors are interrelated and the effects of some of them may be much greater than those of others and there may be locational variations in the degree of their effects on productivity. Some of these factors may be under the direct control of all the farmers. Others may be controlled by groups of other farmers, managers at the system level and policy-makers at higher levels. Yet some of these are beyond human control (Rahman, 2003). Various other studies have documented some of these factors. Other factors that abound in economic literature include technology, labour employment, education and training of farm operators, agro-environmental conditions, security of land ownership rights and funding which determines the maximal physical quantity of output that can be reached as well as the number and quantity of inputs required (Stefanon and Saxena, 1988; Gorton and Davidova, 2004; Benjamin, 1995; Christiou, 2001; Huffman and Evenson, 2003).

          Productivity differences over time or across farming types can result from variety of factors. These factors include:
ü Difference in efficiency (less than the maximum output is produced from a given input applied);
ü Venation in scale or level of production over time as the output per unit of input varies with the scale of production; and
ü Technical change (Ahearn, Yee, Ball and Nehring, 1998).
          Productivity varies over time on account of the farmer’s rationality in resource use and as a consequent of economic policies, environment (Kaur, and Sekhon, 2005), infrastructure, cropping systems and management practices at the plot level.
                   
Concept of Efficiency
          The concept of efficiency can be said to deal with the relative performance of the processes used in the transformation of inputs into outputs. Economic theory’s discussion of efficiency distinguishes it into two types; allocative efficiency and technical efficiency. Farrell (1957) one of the pioneers of efficiency studies distinguished the two types of efficiency through the use of the frontier production function (Xu and Jeffrey, 1998). Technical efficiency is defined by the duo as the ability to produce a given level of output with a minimum quantity of inputs under certain technology. Allocative efficiency refers to the ability of choosing optimal input levels for given factor prices. The total efficiency otherwise called economic efficiency is the product of technical and allocative efficiency. The degree to which technical and allocative efficiency are achieved is referred to as production efficiency.

         Farm efficiency measurement is very important both in developed and developing agriculture. Its role in increasing agricultural output is widely recognized by researchers and policy makers, for example, Bravo-Ureta and Evenson (1994). There are three distinct approaches to farm efficiency measurement, while some are based on costs called cost frontier approach others are based on profit and production function approaches. Numerous methods have been developed for the empirical measurement of frontier functions and the potential deviations from such functions. These methods can be categorized according to the specification of the frontier – parametric or non-parametric; the way the frontier is computed, through programming or statistical procedures, and the way deviation from the frontier are interpreted, that is as inefficiency or a mixture of inefficiency and statistical noise.

          Efficiency is a very important factor of productivity growth especially in developing agrarian economies, where resources are meager and opportunities for developing and adopting better technologies are dwindling. Such economies can benefit from efficiency studies which show that it is possible to raise productivity by improving efficiency without increasing the resource base or developing new technologies. Raising productivity and output of small farmers would not only increase their incomes and food security, but also stimulate the rest of the economy and contribute to broad-based food security and poverty alleviation (Lipton, 2005).
 
Theoretical Framework
          The framework for the study is developed from interplay of the theory of agricultural production, agricultural programme intervention (Presidential Initiatives on cassava) and technical efficiency in agricultural productivity. A production function is the technical relationship between inputs and outputs; that is, a function that summarizes the process of conversion of factors into a particular commodity. It shows the maximum amount of the goods that can be produced using alternative combinations of the various inputs. Pioneering studies that looked at the efficiency of farms are those by Koopman (1951) and Farrell (1957). The relevance of efficiency in increasing agricultural production has been widely recognized and variously investigated by researchers such as Bravo-Ureta, (1993); Ashok et al., (1995); Seyoum, (1998); Abay, Miran and Gunden, (2004); Chavas, Petrie and Roth, (2005).

Empirical Review of Related Literature
          A study by Battese and Coelli (1995) on paddy rice farms in Aurepalle India used panel data for 10 years and concluded that older farmers were less efficient than the younger ones. Farmers with more years of schooling were also found to be more efficient, but this declined over time; this is expected as farmers grow older the energy to do the tedious farm activities tend to decrease with age. Battese et al., (1996) used a single stage stochastic frontier model to estimate technical efficiency in the production process of wheat farmers in the four districts of Pakistan, the result obtained ranged between 57 and 79 percent. According to them the older farmers had smaller technical inefficiencies as expected. Seyoum et al., (1998) in measuring technical efficiency of maize farmers in Eastern Ethiopia for farmers within and outside the Sasa-kawa Global 2000 project used a translog stochastic production function and a Cobb-Douglas production function. One of their conclusions is that younger farmers are more technically efficient than the older farmers; also farmers with more years of schooling tend to be more efficient. Those who received more extension information tended to reduce technical in-efficiency the more. The mean technical efficiency of farmers within the SG 2000 project was estimated to be 0.94 while farmers outside the project had 0.79.
Share on Google Plus

Declaimer - Unknown

The publications and/or documents on this website are provided for general information purposes only. Your use of any of these sample documents is subjected to your own decision NB: Join our Social Media Network on Google Plus | Facebook | Twitter | Linkedin

READ RECENT UPDATES HERE