THEORETICAL LITERATURE OF INTERACTION BETWEEN INDUSTRIAL GROWTH AND COMMERCIAL BANK CREDIT



Some research effort has been devoted to examining the linkages between financial instability and down turns in industrial growth. One major observation is that money market booms and busts have preceded banking crises not only in developed countries Davis (1999) and Renaud (1999).
Based on the above hypotheses of financial sector cycles, there are at least three dimensions of INTERACTION BETWEEN INDUSTRIAL GROWTH AND COMMERCIAL BANK CREDIT. First, bank interest rates may affect the
volume of bank credit for various reasons. From the borrowers’ point of view, changes in the interest rates of banks will have a large effect on their perceived wealth and borrowing capacity, inducing them to change their borrowing plans and credit demand (given positive costs of bankruptcy when net worth becomes negative). The low liquidity and interest rate volatility of various bank services/products should induce caution among borrowers in taking full account of loans for credit rises. However, from the banks’ point of view, banks have been involved in financial markets not only directly by owning investment loans, but also by providing credit that are collateralized by assets. Giving credit to property and construction companies along is one of the most procyclical and volatile elements of banks’ provisioning.
Davis, 1993, accordingly adding these mechanisms together, changes in property prices will have major impacts on banks’ asset quality and the value of bank capital, and therefore affect banks’ credit capacity. Banks are willing to provide more investment credits and property prices are higher, generating a propagation mechanism through which credit cycles are strongly linked with each other. Such a cycle may be exacerbated by capital inflows intermediated by domestic banks, as in East Asia in the mid 1990s, as well as poor regulation (Collyns and Senhadji, 2002).
A further complementary effect may operate via the above mentioned financial accelerator mechanism, whereby credit givers become less concerned about moral hazard and adverse selection when net worth is high, as borrowers have more to lose from default. This implies that changes in asset prices over the cycle gives rise to procyclical feedback effects of agency costs on the cost of external finance and hence on real corporate expenditures. This channel might be more powerful if banks tend to underestimate the default risk of investment related loans in a business boom and the moral hazard to which borrowers financing business investments are subject. In practice, this tendency can be the result of various factors, including poor risk management practice, inadequate data or pervasive incentives of banks, including moral hazard linked to the safety net (Herring and Wacher, 2002).
Second, bank credit may affect industrial development via various liquidity effects. Changes in credit availability and credit attitudes have a sizable impact on the demand for real investment decisions, which will ultimately lead to changes in economic prices. Zhu, (2002), it has been widely documented that floods of capital seeking investment opportunities and the industrial competition among financial institutions after financial deregulation helped to stimulate the building frenzy phenomenon in a number of countries in the 1980s and 1990s, Davis (1995) and Demirgue-Kunt and Detragiache (1998).
Hargraves et al (1993) note in addition that financial liberalization tends to derive the higher quality corporate borrowers  to the bond market and depositors to money funds, thus leading banks to take excessive risks to re-establish margins. Finally, credit cycles can be driven by common economic factors. Its behaviour is largely determined by economic conditions and prospects (notably GDP and interest rates). On the other hand, the state of economic activity also exerts important forces on the money market. Changes in the business environment will cause demand and supply imbalances in commercial property and generate variations in investments and prises. These external shocks can arise from the demand side, such as changes in income. Interest rates and demographic factors; or they can arise from the supply side such as input costs as well as changes in restrictions enhancing the availability of credit or land for development (Dokko et al 1999), Chen and Patel (1998).
Financial disclosure and business information transparency is a critical element in ensuring more stable capital flows. Effective debtor-creditor and insolvency regimes are critical to absorbing business failure and releasing assets for productivity use, hence bank credit are essential ingredients in overcoming industrial sector crises, IMF (2004).
Commercial bank provides resources for social sector programmes to reduce the impact of poor infrastructure on industrial crises. In the Republic of Korea, banks helped the government create a financial supervisory commission and a financial supervisory service combining four regulatory agencies. Banks are helping the government support numerous small no medium enterprises, which are under stress from the financial crises, in restructuring liabilities and increasing their demand for credit. In Thailand, banks helped recapitalise other financial intermediaries, strengthen the legal and regulatory framework for the financial sector, and stress to specialized financial institutions capacity to increase credit in order to ease credit contraction. Outside East Asia, banks have provided credit or non-credits services with some degree of financial sector vulnerability, including financial sector assessment policy reviews and intensive dialogue with government authorities.
          There are many reasons why formula provision of financial services may be limited in Nigeria and other developing countries, even after liberalization. High levels of government debt have often constrained access to credit for private firms and individuals, and high inflation has discouraged saving. Poor physical and institutional infrastructure (e.g intermittent electricity supplies, inadequate telecommunications services, weak institutions for contract enforcement etc) raise the cost of provision, particularly to poor and rural areas. At the same time, poorer people have no collateral or credit record and many countries lack credit bureau, all of which serve to deter credit giving. Regulatory requirements that guard against money laundering can also make it difficult for poor people to open a bank account, as they may not have the necessary documentation. Thus widening access to financial services may simply be unprofitable in many cases. Indeed, given the many types of market failures present in financial services, the market is likely to under-provide. It is also the case that weak competition policy in some countries has results in quite a concentrated financial sector even after liberalization, allowing high spread to persist, which blunts incentives to expand access to unfamiliar and risky market segments, even where they may be potentially profitable. And a lack of detailed information about the characteristics of these market segments has made it difficult for financial institutions to correctly assess the costs and risk associated with expanding access to credit.
          According to the theories of corporate credit or finance, there are three main categories of sources to finance the investment: first the internal finance, which depends on the retained earnings of the firm, the only cost of this kind is the shareholders return and the opportunity cost of this fund. Second, debt finance, this kind may be secured debt or unsecured debt, which include loans, bonds, this cost of these kinds represent in the interest payable plus any premium on repayment. Third equity finance, share issues, ordinary and preference, the cost of these kinds are earning price per share (EPS) and fixed dividend company should not only alter its capital structure to take advantage of changes in the explicit and implicit cost of various source of finance, but also to maximize control and capital gearing for the company. External factors represented by the degree of the development of the financial system and the changes in its structure affect the investment decision Modighani and Miller (1958).
          According to the theory of investment, in the absence of financial restriction, firm investment depends on the (q ratio) or the q value of the firm, which equal to the market value of the firm to its replacement value, Jorgensem (1971).
When the firm faces constraints on external finance its internal resources will determine its investment. The degree of leverage of the firm (debt to capital ratio) also depends on the development of the financial sector and its structure. When the firm faces imperfect financial market this ratio decline and deter the availability of external finance, even after controlling the q value, Francisco, Norman, Loyza (2008).
Therefore, we assume that the firms face better function of financial system when investment is more responsive to q Tobin. Investment is less determined by the firm cash flow. Investment is less negative affected by the firm liability composition. There are a lot of applied literature investigated on this issue, due to financial liberalization and the substantial change in the structure of the financial market they concentrate on the effect of such change on the growth and investment at the firm level.
          The most recent literatures are the study of Marten Comelmen: describe the developments that have transpired in Mexico’s financial structure over the last two decades. Then he analyzed how the increase in credit to the private sector brought about by these macroeconomic and financial developments affected output and investment in different sectors and therefore, growth in the Mexican economy. He argued that an increase in the availability of credit has a relatively large effect on the output of those sectors such as manufactures, durables, construction, and investment in the construction sector.
The financial sector limits, prices, pools and trades all the risks involved in a transaction and provide incentives for savers to invest by matching potential earnings with those risks. In contrast, distorted financial markets with high macroeconomic instability, direct government involvement and weak regulations can have extremely adverse effects on industrial sector and on economic growth in general. As a result, the focus of much recent work on the financial sector has been on deepening and broadening financial markets in developing countries and on improving financial sector regulation, supervision and governance. The increasing participation of commercial banks has been one of the most striking structural changes experienced by banking systems in developing countries over the past decade.
In Nigeria the number of banks stands at 24 due to the recent consolidation exercise. Common argument against bank credit is that banks might tend to “cheery pick” the most profitable customers, reducing financial risks and thus, affecting the overall distribution of credit. In particular, the main area of concern is the availability of credit to private investors and small firms. In many developing countries, small firms account for a very significant share of total value added and generate a large fraction of the total jobs in the economy.
Commercial banks are perceived as having a comparative advantage over other credit institutions in small business credit. This role is likely to be more important in less developed countries that are generally more heavily dependent on bank financing. In Argentina for example, 79 percent of small industrial firms have bank debt (Lorens, Van der Host, and Isusi, 1999).
Moreover, small firms tend to have exclusive dealings with a single bank with which they have a strong relationship, given the paucity of information on the risk characteristics of individual investors or small firms. Therefore, access to credit by private investors and small firms would be reduced if banks were to neglect small firms and/or drive domestic micro-finance banks from the market, destroying the information generated through bank-borrower relationship.  It have been argued that commercial banks seems to improve banking systems efficiency in the provision of credit to investors and contribute to overall banking stability in developing countries (See Dermirgue-Kunt, Levine, and Min (1998), Levine (1999), Barajas et al (2000). On the other hand, the effect of bank credit on industrial sector in developing countries especially in Nigeria remains largely unexplored. While large banks are unlikely to replicate the credit methods of small domestic micro finances banks technological innovation could offer them an avenue for increasing small firm’s credit.
Mester (1997) argues that advances in credit scoring methodologies, together with enhanced computer power and increased data availability, are likely to change the nature of small business credit. This suggests that there could be a non-linear and in particular U-shaped relation between bank size and credit to small firms. The literature for the US also suggests that the type of bank may affect credit patterns. For example, the evidence from the U.S. indicates that de novo entrants seem to devote larger shares of their assets to small firms than other banks (Goldberg and White, 1998. Deyoung et al, 1999 and Jenkins (2000).
Commercial bank entry through merger and acquisition might have different effects on small firm credit. Some studies find that, merger and acquisitions among small banks led to increased propensity to give credit to small firms following their consolidation (Peek and Rosengren, 1998), Walraven, 1997), Strahan and Weston (1998), Berger et al (1998).
Using the Kaminsky and Reinhard (1999) framework, Pugh and Dehesh (2001) argued that financial liberalization has contributed to a closer interdependence between property and industrial sector developments in a number of countries since the 1980s. In addition, some recent studies have looked into the real effects of house price fluctuations.
Hendershott and kane (1992) noted that the early 1990s credit crunch in the United states could be partly attributed to capital rebuilding by financial institutions that had made large real estate loses. Moreover, on the demand side, the recession itself may have linked to a collapse in investment reflecting excessive capital formation in terms of real estate. Ludwig and Slok (2002) suggested that, in market-based economies, housing prices tend to have a significant effect on consumption, similar is provided by Boone et al (2001) and Barrell and Davis (2004).
Laporta, lopez-de Silanes, Shleifer and Vishny, (1999), Modigliani and Perotti (1998), argued that the legal system in a country is a primary determination of the effectiveness of its financial market based and bank based. Financial systems may not be of primary importance for policy in the absence of a strong legal system that can protect the rights of external investors, which financial transactions are intermediated through.
Share on Google Plus

Declaimer - Unknown

The publications and/or documents on this website are provided for general information purposes only. Your use of any of these sample documents is subjected to your own decision NB: Join our Social Media Network on Google Plus | Facebook | Twitter | Linkedin

READ RECENT UPDATES HERE