M. Sc. RESEARCH FINDINGS
DEPARTMENT OF AGRICULTURAL ECONOMICS, MANAGEMENT, AND EXTENSION
FACULTY OF AGRICULTURE AND
NATURAL RESOURCES MANAGEMENT
ABSTRACT
Funding Ebonyi State agricultural public
extension service in a deregulated economy was studied. The specific objectives
analyzed include to describe the socio-economic characteristics of the
respondents; identify the major recommended packages/technologies and services
extended to the farmers by the extension agents; describe the trend in the
funding of agricultural extension services between 2001 and 2010; ascertain
farmers’ willingness to pay for extension services; analyse the effects of
farmers socio-economic characteristics on their ability to pay for extension
services and identified constraints against farmers’ willingness to pay for
extension services in a deregulated economy. A total of 240 contact farmers
were selected using a multistage random sampling technique. Data collected were
analysed using both descriptive and inferential statistics. The study found
that majority (65.42%) of the respondents were males; had a mean age of 49
years, married; had a relatively large household size of 8 persons; and
relatively low educational status. Average farm holding was 0.90 ha and
personal savings were the major sources of farm finance. Government funding of the agricultural public
extension (ADP) dwindled throughout the period with budget estimate at the peak
of N220.4m recorded in 2009 and the
lowest of about N69.3m in 2001, whereas
the highest actual expenditure was about N99.5m
in 2004 and the lowest amount of about N37.1m
was also recorded in 2001. A very great difference between the budget estimate
and actual expenditure was observed in 2004 with about 46.5%. The amount
farmers were willing to pay for extension services was not also stable with the
highest amount of about N9.2m in 2005
and least amount of N800,000.00 in
2003. The amount expended by government was much more higher than the amount
farmers are willing to pay with 98.2% difference in 2004. Majority (67.08%) of
the respondents were not willing to pay for extension service while about 10%
of them showed future willingness to pay. High proportion of those willing to
pay indicated 21-40% degree of willingness. Furthermore, about 88% and 48% of
the respondents noted that deregulation of extension services will cause
specialized training for farmers to improve, and most farmers will not be able
to afford payment for extension services, respectively. Major extension
services the respondents were willing to pay for include the cost of arranging
for farm input supply; cost to access farm machinery; extension agents’ home
and farm visits; and cost of processing loans. However, the highest mean amount
farmers were willing to pay were recorded for loan processing (N8,100), followed by cost to arrange farm
input supply (N6,450) and support for
farm radio programme (N6,100). Results
of probit multiple regression indicated that educational level, farming
experience, farm income, farm size and frequency of extension contact has positive significant effect on
farmer’s willingness to pay for extension in a deregulated economy, while age
and household size had a significant negative effect. R2 and
chi-square values of 0.512 and 30.965, respectively, showed that the
socio-economic characteristic of the respondents had effect on their
willingness to pay for extension services in the study area. Major constraints
that limit farmers’ willingness to pay for extension services were identified,
using factor analysis, as financial, social, and institutional constraints.
Generally, the study indicated that the proportion of farmers willing to pay
for extension services is low. This could lead to reduced adoption and
utilization of improved technologies and subsequent decline in farmer and farm
productivity in a deregulated economy.
Necessary recommendations such as
educating farmers on cost of extension services and the need for their
contribution, backing up extension services with interest free loans,
deregulating extension services should be a gradual process and in phases, and
improving the country’s educational system were made among others.
TABLE
OF CONTENTS
Abstract
Tables
of contents
List
of tables
List
of figures
List
of Appendix
CHAPTER
ONE
INTRODUCTION
1.1
Background
Information
1.2
Problem
Statement
1.3
Objective
of the Study
1.4
Hypothesis
1.5 Justification for the Study
CHAPTER
TWO
LITERATURE
REVIEW
2.1
Meaning and Concept of Deregulation
2.2
Deregulation in Nigeria Economy
2.3
Deregulation and Extension Service
2.4
Meaning and Concept of Fund
2.5
Funding Extension Services in Nigeria
2.6 Ebonyi State Agricultural
Development Programme (EBADEP)
2.6.1 EBADEP Specific Projects Currently Funded by Donor Agencies, Federal and State Governments
CHAPTER
THREE
METHODOLOGY
3.1 The Study Area
3.2 Sampling Technique
3.3 Data Collection
3.4Analytical Technique
3.5 Model
Specification
3.5.1 Probit Multiple Regression Model
3.5.2 Ordinary Least Square (OLS)
Assumptions
CHAPTER
FOUR
RESULTS
4.1 Socio-Economic
Characteristics of Respondents
4.2 Major Packages/Technologies and Services Extended to Farmers by Extension
Agents
4.2.2 Extension Services Rendered to the Farmers by Extension Agents
4.3 Trend in Funding of Agricultural Extension
Services in Ebonyi State between
4.4 Farmers Willingness to Pay
for Extension Services Rendered By
ADP in Ebonyi State.
4.4.1
Willingness to Pay (WTP) by Farmers
4.4.2 Future
Willingness to Pay for Extension Services
4.4.3 Degree of
Future Willingness to Pay for Extension Services
4.4.4 Amount
Farmers are willing to pay for Extension Services in 2001-2010
4.4.5 Comparism Between the Amount Expended by Government and that the
Farmers were Willing to Pay
4.5 Effects of Farmers
Socio-Economic Characteristics on their Willingness to Pay for
Extension Services
4.6 Constraints to Farmer's Willingness to Pay for
Extension Services in a Deregulated Economy
4.7 Hypothesis Testing
CHAPTER
FIVE
DISCUSSION
5.1 Socio-Economic
Characteristics of Respondents
5.2 Major
Packages/Technologies and Services Extended to Farmers by Extension Agents
5.3 Trend in
Funding of Agricultural Extension Services in Ebonyi State Between 2000 and 2009
5.5
Effects of Farmers' Socio-Economic Characteristics on their Willingness to Pay for Extension Services
5.6 Constraints against Farmers Willingness to Pay for Extension
Services in a Deregulated Economy
CHAPTER SIX
SUMMARY,
CONCLUSION AND RECOMMENDATIONS
6.1 Summary
6.2 Conclusion
6.3 Recommendations
References
Questionnaira
Appendix
List
of tables
Table 1: Distrinution
of Respondents Based on their Socio-Economic Characteristics
(N = 240)
Table 2: Distribution
of Respondents Based on Major Packages/Technologies Extended to
the Respondents
Table 3: Distribution
of Respondents Based on Extension Services Rendered
to them by Extension Agents
Table 4: Animal
Expenditure on Agricultural Extension Service in Ebonyi State, Nigeria
Table 5: Distribution
of Respondents based on WTP opinion
Table 6: Distribution
of Resonpondents Based on Future Willingness to
Pay for Extension Services
Table 7: Distribution
of Respondents Based on their Degree of future Willingness
to Pay for Extension Services
Table 8: Amount
Farmers are willing to pay for various Technologies
Table 9: Comparism
between Amount Expended and that the Fermers are
willing to Pay
Table 10: Distribution of Respondents Based on Perceived Effects of Deregulated Economy
on Extension Service Delivery
Table 12: Distribution of Respondents Based on the Extension Services they are willing to Pay
for and Mean Amount
Table 12: Probit Multiple regression Results of Effect of Farmers’ Socio-Economic
Characteristics on Willingness to Pay for Extension
Table 13: Varimax Rotated factor Matrix on Constraints Limiting Famers’
Willingness to pay Extension Services in the study Area.
LIST OF FIGURES
Figure 1: Annual Expenditure on Agricultural Extension Service in Ebonyi State
Nigeria
Figure 2: Amount Farmers are willing to pay in the study Area
Figure 3: Estimated Amount Expended by Government and that the Farmers are willing
to pay
LIST OF APPENDIX
Appendix 1: Logistic Regression Result of Determinants of Respondents’
Willingness to Pay for Extension Services.
Appendix II: Factor Analysis on Constraints against Farmers’ Willingness
to Pay for Extension Services in he Study Area.
CHAPTER
FOUR
RESULTS
In this chapter,
data collected from the field were analyzed accordingly, based on the stated
objectives using appropriate statistical techniques. The result obtained is
presented in sub-sections hereunder:
4.1 Socio-Economic Characteristics of Respondents
The socio-economic characteristics of the respondents (farmers) were
examined and the results obtained are presented in Table 1.
Table 1: Distribution of Respondents Based on their
Socio-Economic Characteristics (N = 240)
Socio-economic variables
|
Frequency
|
Percentage
|
Sex
|
||
Male
|
157
|
65.42
|
Female
|
83
|
34.58
|
Total
|
240
|
100
|
Age (Years)
|
||
21-30
|
14
|
5.83
|
31-40
|
30
|
12.50
|
41-50
|
72
|
30.00
|
51-60
|
114
|
47.50
|
61-70
|
10
|
4.17
|
Total
Marital Status
|
240
|
100
|
Single
|
13
|
5.42
|
Married
|
171
|
71.25
|
Widow/widower
|
35
|
14.58
|
Divorced
|
21
|
8.75
|
Total
|
240
|
100
|
Household Size
|
||
1-3
|
20
|
8.33
|
4-6
|
36
|
15.00
|
7-9
|
70
|
29.17
|
10-12
|
114
|
47.50
|
Total
|
240
|
100
|
Educational level
|
||
No formal
education
|
85
|
35.42
|
Primary
education
|
77
|
32.08
|
Secondary
education
|
43
|
17.92
|
Tertiary
education
|
35
|
14.58
|
Total
|
240
|
100
|
Annual Farm Income
|
||
21-40
|
30
|
12.50
|
41-60
|
61
|
25.40
|
61-70
|
80
|
33.33
|
71-80
|
45
|
18.75
|
81-90
|
15
|
6.25
|
91-100
|
9
|
3.75
|
Total
|
240
|
100
|
Source of Funds
|
||
Personal savings
|
169
|
70.42
|
Informal loan
|
37
|
15.41
|
Bank
|
19
|
7.92
|
Grant
|
10
|
4.17
|
Gift
|
5
|
2.08
|
Total
|
240
|
100
|
Farm Size (Ha)
|
||
0.1-0.5
|
105
|
43.75
|
0.6-1.0
|
71
|
29.58
|
1.1-1.5
|
13
|
5.42
|
1.6-2.0
|
24
|
10.00
|
2.1-2.5
|
17
|
7.08
|
2.6-3.0
|
10
|
4.17
|
Total
|
240
|
100
|
Farming Experience (years)
|
||
1.0 – 1.0
|
18
|
7.50
|
11-20
|
22
|
9.17
|
21-30
|
50
|
20.83
|
31-40
|
120
|
50.00
|
41-50
|
20
|
8.33
|
51-60
|
10
|
4.17
|
Total
|
240
|
100
|
Frequency of Extension contacts
|
||
Once in 2 weeks
|
23
|
9.58
|
Once in 4 weeks
|
177
|
73.75
|
Once in 8 weeks
|
40
|
16.69
|
Total
|
240
|
100
|
Land Tenure
|
||
Owned
|
166
|
69.17
|
Rented
|
74
|
30.83
|
Total
|
240
|
100
|
Source: Field Survey, 2010
Table 1 presents the socio-economic characteristics of the farmers.
Majority (65.42%) of the respondents were males, and about 48% of the respondents were in the age brackets of 51 - 60 years, followed by those
who were in the age bracket of 41 - 50 years with 30%. The
least percentage (4.17%) of the respondents were in the age
bracket of 61 -70 years. However, the mean age of the respondents was
49 years. Majority of the respondents
representing about 71% were married while about 5% were single. About 15% indicated that they are either
widow or widower. The results also
showed that most (47.50%) of the respondents had a large household size of between 10 and 12 persons with
just about 8% having a household size of 1 - 3 persons. The mean household size
was found to be about 8 persons.
Again, the level of education of the respondents was relatively high as
up to 65% of the respondents had one form of formal education or the other. The highest percentage (32.08%) of those educated was observed at the
primary education
level. However, about 33% of them attained either secondary or
tertiary education level while 35.42% had no formal education. The mean annual farm income of the farmers was N61, 562.50 with the highest percentage of them earning between N61,000 - N70,000. About
4% and 13% of the
respondents earned between N91, 000 - N100, 000 and N21,000- N40,000 respectively. Table 1 also
indicated that the respondents'
major source of funding for their farming activities was their personal saving shown by 70% of them.
This was followed by informal loan with
15.41% while 8% indicated that the formal sources (Banks) were their major source of fund for their farm activities.
The average farm
holding was 0.90ha. Most (43.75%) had a farm size of between 0.1 and 0.5ha while about 4% and 30% had between 2.6 - 3.0ha
and 0.6 - l.0 ha of farmland,
respectively. Result on farming experience of the farmers indicated that 50% of them had been in the business of
farming for between 31-40 years, and
about 21% of them for between 21 - 30 years. Only about 4% and 8% had farmed
for 51 -60 years and 1 - 10 years, respectively. The mean fanning
experience was however 31 years. Findings as
shown on the table further showed that about 74% of the respondents were
visited once per month (4 weeks) by an extension agent, and about 17% were visited once in 2 months (8 weeks). Only about 10%
were visited once in two (2) weeks.
Based in tenurial system, majority (69.17%)
of the respondents owned the land they cultivate and about 31% rented the land they used (Table 1).
4.2 Major
Packages/Technologies and Services Extended to Farmers
by Extension Agents
4.2.1 Major Packages/Technologies to Farmers
The major recommended technologies extended to farmers by the state ADP
were identified, and the result is presented in table 2.
Table 2:
Distribution of Respondents Based on Major Packages/Technologies
Extended to the Respondents
Package/Technology
Extended
|
Frequency
|
Percentage
|
Dry season vegetable production (Exotic vegetable production, mulching,
using organic manure and correct spacing)
|
65
|
27.08
|
Yam/Maize/Vegetable (rapid seed yam multiplication, improved maize
varieties, spacing and fertilizer application
|
101
|
42.08
|
Cassava/maize/sweet potatoes (use of improved varieties of cassava,
maize and sweet potato, and soil enrichment with potato)
|
151
|
62.92
|
Cassava/maize/melon (row planting, spacing, improved varieties and
fertilizer application)
|
60
|
25.00
|
Late maize/cowpea/soybean (improved varieties, soil enrichment with
soyabean or cowpea and use of pesticides)
|
51
|
21.25
|
Swamp rice production (improved varieties, early planting, line
planting, and pest and diseases control in rice field with emphasis on
African Rice Gall midge (AFRGM)
|
171
|
71.25
|
Upland rice production (NERICA), use and time of fertilizer application
|
120
|
50.00
|
Processing cassava/sweet patato into floor (peeling, washing, grading,
drying, milling, and sieving that is adding value and increasing shelf life)
|
47
|
19.58
|
Utilization of cassava/sweet potato flour (measuring ingredients,
mixing, kneading, baking or frying and packaging)
|
70
|
29.17
|
Production of fruit juices, processing and utilization of soyabean
(selection, washing, blending, sieving, cooling and storage)
|
61
|
25.43
|
Total
|
897*
|
*MultipIe responses recorded
The results in
Table 2 indicated that the major technologies extended to the farmers in the area were those associated with swamp rice
production, and cassava/maize/sweet
potatoes mixed cropping as identified by 71.25% and 62.92% of the respondents, respectively. The least identified was processing
cassava/sweet potatoes into flour with about 20%. Other packages/technologies
identified by respondents as being extended to them include those of yam/maize/vegetable mixed cropping (42.08%), upland
rice production (NERICA) (50%) and
utilization of cassava/sweet potato flour (29.17%), among others. However, the multiple responses recorded indicated that the respondent identified more than
one package/technology.
4.2.2
Extension Services Rendered to the Farmers by Extension Agents
The extension services rendered to farmers by the State ADP Extension Agents were identified and the result is presented in Table 3.
Table 3: Distribution of
Respondents Based on Extension Services Rendered to them by Extension Agent
Extension
Services Rendered
Frequency Percentage
|
||
Establishment
of SPAT
|
131
|
54.58
|
Forming women groups
|
50
|
20.83
|
Providing information to women farmers
|
61
|
25.42
|
Identifying
rural problems
|
98
|
40.83
|
Involvement in non-farming activities
|
81
|
33.75
|
Supervising
women activities
|
75
|
31.25
|
Arrange input supply
|
181
|
75.42
|
Preparing schedule of activities
|
100
|
41.67
|
Processing loan
|
41
|
17.08
|
Initiating and promoting leadership
|
71
|
29.58
|
Securing market for shows and farm produce
|
66
|
27.50
|
Organizing
shows
|
90
|
37.50
|
Organizing group meetings
|
98
|
40.83
|
Communication of recommended practices
|
198
|
82.50
|
Feeding
back farmers’ problems to research
|
121
|
50.42
|
Teaching new ideas in agriculture
|
200
|
83.33
|
Teaching how to keep record of activity
|
170
|
70.83
|
Giving advice on agricultural problems
|
210
|
87.50
|
Home and farm visits
|
215
|
89.58
|
Helping with access to farm machinery
|
82
|
34.17
|
Total
|
2339*
|
Source: Field Survey, 2010. *Multiple Responses
recorded
The multiple responses recorded indicated that more than
one services were
extended to the farmers by the extension agents. On the average, each
respondent received about ten (10) services from the extension agents in the
area. Majority of the respondents received such services as home and farm visits (89.58%), advice on their agricultural
problems (87.50%), learning new ideas
on agriculture (83.33%), and information on recommended practices (82.50%). Other services enjoyed by the
farmers from the extension agents
were the arrangement for input supply (75.42%), keeping record of farm
activity (70.83%), establishment of SPAT (54.58%), feeding back the farmers
problems to research (50.42%), preparing schedule for activities (41.67%), organizing group meetings (40.83%) and identifying rural
problems (40.83%), among others. However, the least service received from the extension agents was in the area of
processing of loan with 17.08%.
4.3 Trend in
Funding of Agricultural Extension Services in Ebonyi State between
2001 and 2010.
The trend in funding public agricultural extension services in Ebonyi
State was reviewed, and the annual approved estimate of Agricultural Extension
service and actual expenditure, and the difference between budget estimate and
the actual expenditure were obtained from Ebonyi State Government (Ministry of
Finance and Economic Development) and Ebonyi State Agricultural Development
Programme (EBADEP). The results were presented in Tables 4, 5 and 6 and Figures
1, 2 and 3 respectively.
Table
4: Annual Approved Estimates on Agricultural Extension Service in Ebonyi State
(2001-2010).
YEAR
|
AMOUNT
(
|
2001
|
69, 301, 000
|
2002
|
109, 048, 110
|
2003
|
94, 500, 000
|
2004
|
129, 000,000
|
2005
|
160, 629, 796
|
2006
|
88, 250,000
|
2007
|
115, 600, 000
|
2008
|
105, 000, 000
|
2009
|
220, 400,000
|
2010
|
124, 100,000
|
Source: EBSG (Ministry of Finance), 2010.
The
result in Table 4, Figures 1 and 2 indicated that there was no steady increase
in the total amount approved by Ebonyi State Government within the years of
study for extension service delivery. The amount approved increased and
decreased form year to year. However, the highest estimate was approved in 2009
with N220, 400,000, while the lowest
estimate was approved in 2001 with N69,
301, 000. Further, there was a great decline from N220, 400,000 in 2009 to N124,
100, 000 in 2010.
Table
5: Annual Actual Expenditure on Agricultural Extension Service in Ebonyi State
(2001-2010)
YEAR
|
AMOUNT
(
|
2001
|
37, 127, 792
|
2002
|
39, 774, 630
|
2003
|
42, 840, 089
|
2004
|
99, 459, 694
|
2005
|
93, 666, 054
|
2006
|
44, 747, 723
|
2007
|
57, 957, 757
|
2008
|
55, 241, 172
|
2009
|
90, 962, 428
|
2010
|
93, 975, 943
|
Sources:
EBADEP, 2010
The result in
Table 5, Figures 2A and 2B indicated inconsistency and unstable funding
of agricultural extension service in Ebonyi State.
The
amount spent every year within the period of study did not continuously
increase or decrease. Year 2001 was the year of least funding with N37, 127, 792; while the highest amount of
fund was expended on agricultural extension services in the year 2004, with N99, 459, 694. A decrease in funding was
observed in 2005 and with a very sharp decrease in 2006. However, a gradual
increase occurred between 2007 and 2008, with another sharp increase recorded
in 2009 and 2010.
Table
6: Different Between Budgets Estimate and Actual Expenditure on Agricultural
Extension service in Ebonyi State.
Year
|
Budget
Estimate (
|
Actual
Expenditure (
|
Difference
(
|
Percentage
Difference
(%)
|
2001
|
69,301,000
|
37,127,792
|
32,173,208
|
30.2
|
2002
|
109,048,110
|
39,774,630
|
69,273,480
|
46.5
|
2003
|
94,500,000
|
42,840,089
|
51,659,911
|
37.6
|
2004
|
129,000,000
|
99,459,694
|
29,540,206
|
12.9
|
2005
|
160,629,796
|
93,666,054
|
66,963,742
|
26.3
|
2006
|
88,250,000
|
44,747,723
|
43,502,277
|
32.7
|
2007
|
115,600,000
|
57,957,757
|
57,642,243
|
33.2
|
2008
|
105,000,000
|
55,241,172
|
49,758,828
|
31.0
|
2009
|
220,400,000
|
90,962,428
|
129,437,572
|
41.6
|
2010
|
124,100,000
|
93,975,943
|
30,124,057
|
13.8
|
Source: Field Survey, 2010.
The result
obtained in Table 6, Figures 3A and 3B reveals that there
is a great difference between the budget estimate and the actual expenditure on
agricultural extension service delivery in Ebonyi State. The greatest
difference was witnessed in 2004 with a percentage difference of 77.1%, closely
followed by 2010 with 75.7% and in 2001 with 53.6%. However, the lowest
difference was obtained in 2002 with 36.5%.
4.4 Farmers
Willingness to Pay for Extension Services Rendered by
ADP in
Ebonyi State.
Farmers Willingness to
Pay for extension services rendered by ADP in Ebonyi State was examined. The
Willingness to Pay (WTP) by the farmers, future Willingness to Pay, degree of
Willingness to Pay, amount farmers are willing to pay, and comparism between
the amount expended by government and the amount farmers are willing to pay
were ascertained.
The perception of farmers towards extension service in a deregulated
economy and extension services farmers are willing to pay for and the amount
were also examined. The results are presented in Tables 7, 8, 9, 10, 11, 12 and
13, and Figures 4 and 5.
4.4.1 Willingness to Pay (WTP) by
Farmers
The farmers’ willingness to pay for extension services rendered in the study area was
ascertained. The result is presented in Table 7.
Table
7: Percentage Distribution of Willingness to Pay for Extension Services in the Study Area.
WTP
|
Total
|
Male
|
Female
|
Yes No
|
79(32.92) 161(67.08)
|
59(24.58)
98(40.83)
|
20(8.34) 63(26.25)
|
Total
|
240(100.00)
|
157(65.41)
|
83(34.59)
|
Source: Field Survey, 2010.
The results on Table 7 indicated that about 33% of the respondents were willing to pay for extension services rendered to them while about
67% opined that they were not willing to pay for the
services. Out of the 33% of those willing to pay, about 25% were males and
about 8% were females. About 41% of those not willing to pay for extension
services were males while about 26% were females.
4.4.2 Future Willingness to Pay for Extension Services
According to the results on Table 8, about 57% of the respondents indicated that they are not willing to pay for extension services in the
future. About 43% of the respondents indicated their willingness
to pay for extension services in the future.
Table
8: Distribution of Respondents Based on Future Willingness to Pay for Extension
Services
Ability to Pay in future Frequency Percentage
Yes 103 42.92
No 137 57.08
Total 240 100.00
Source: Field Survey, 2010.
The result
further showed that only about 10% of the respondents who are presently not willing to pay for extension
services indicated their readiness or willingness to pay for extension
services in the future.
4.4.3 Degree of Future Willingness to Pay for Extension
Services
The degree of future willingness
of the farmers to pay for extension services rendered by Extension Personnel
was ascertained, and presented in Table 9.
Table
9: Distribution of Respondents Based on their Degree of Future Willingness to Pay for Extension Services
Degree
(percentage) Frequency
|
Percentage
|
||
1-
|
-20
|
15
|
14.56
|
21
|
-40
|
52
|
50.48
|
41
|
-60
|
23
|
22.33
|
61
|
-80
|
5
|
4.85
|
81
|
-100
|
8
|
7.77
|
Total
|
103*
|
100.00
|
Source: Field Survey, 2010.
About 50% of those willing to pay for extension services showed that they have 21 - 40% degree of willingness to pay while another 22.33% of
the respondents indicated between 41 - 60% degree of willingness to pay. 61 -80% degree of
willingness to pay was indicated by about 5% of the respondents.
4.4.4 Amount Farmers are willing to pay for Extension
Services in 2001-2010.
The amount farmers are willing to pay for extension services delivery
was ascertained from the respondents through primary data and estimated to know the total amount all the farmers in the state would pay. This was summed for the period under study and presented in Table 10 and Figure
4A/4B.
Table
10: Amount Farmers are willing to Pay for Extension Services in 2001-2010
Year
|
Amount (N)
|
2001
|
7,000,000
|
2002
|
3,500,000
|
2003
|
800,000
|
2004
|
920,00
|
2005
|
9,201,232
|
2006
|
1,718,334
|
2007
|
8,358,200
|
2008
|
2,301, 250
|
2009
|
4,273, 239
|
2010
|
3,200,124
|
Source: Field Survey, 2010.
Result obtained in Table 10 and Figure 4A/4B showed
that the actual estimated
amount farmers were willing to pay for some selected extension services
delivery dwindled over the years. It decreased from 7,000,000 to 800,000 from 2001 to 2003 and increased to 920,000
in 2004. A sharp increase to
9,201,232 was recorded in 2005 and this was the peak amount the farmers
were willing to pay within the period under study.
4.4.5
Comparism between the Amount Expended by Government and the amount Farmers are willing to pay
A comparism was
made between the amount the farmers are willing to pay and amount expended by
the government over the years. This was done in
order to discover whether there is any observable difference between them. The result of this comparism is shown in
Table 11 and Figure 5A/5B.
Table 11: Comparism
between Amount Expenditure and the out the Farmers are willing to pay
Year
|
Amount
Expended(
|
Amount Farmers want to pay (
|
Differences
(
|
% difference
|
2001
|
37,127,792
|
7,000,000
|
30,127,792
|
68.3
|
2002
|
39,774,630
|
3,500,000
|
36,274,630
|
83.8
|
2003
|
42,840,089
|
800,000
|
42,040,089
|
96.3
|
2004
|
99,459,694
|
920,000
|
98,539,694
|
98.2
|
2005
|
93,666,054
|
9,201,232
|
84,464,822
|
82.1
|
2006
|
44,747,723
|
1,718,334
|
43,029,389
|
92.6
|
2007
|
57,95,757
|
8,358,200
|
49,599,557
|
74.8
|
2008
|
55,241,172
|
2,301,250
|
52,939,922
|
92.0
|
2009
|
90,962,428
|
4,273,239
|
86,689,189
|
91.0
|
2010
|
93,975,943
|
3,200,124
|
90,775,819
|
93.4
|
Sources: Field Survey, 2010
The result
obtain in Table 11, Figure 5A and 5B revealed that the
actual amount expended on public extension services was very much higher than
the amount farmers are willing to pay. A great difference was witnessed in
2004, 2003, 2010 and 2006 with N98,539,694
(98.2%); N 90,775,819; N 86, 689, 189 and N84,464, 822, respectively.
4.4.6
Perception of Respondents towards Extension Service in a Deregulated Economy
The perception of the farmers on extension service delivery in a deregulated economy was identified, based on the various statements by
the respondents, and the result is presented in Table 12.
Table 12:
Distribution of Respondents Based on Perceived Effects of Deregulated Economy on Extension Service Delivery
Perception
statements
|
Frequency
|
Percentage
|
Extension services will improve
|
98
|
40.83
|
Funding of extension services will be sustainable
|
173
|
72.08
|
Extension agency operation will be more effective
|
90
|
37.50
|
Extension agency operations will be more
specialized
|
70
|
29.17
|
Most farmers will not able to afford payment for
extension services
|
202
|
84.17
|
Farmers will not use extension messages
|
87
|
36.25
|
Rate of adoption of farm technologies will reduce
|
189
|
78.75
|
Commitment of extension agents will improve
|
141
|
58.75
|
Timeliness of extension message will improve
|
160
|
66.67
|
Improvement in extension agents discipline for
service delivery
|
122
|
50.83
|
Farmers will monitor extension agents better
|
65
|
27.08
|
Better reward for extension agents performance
|
17
|
7.08
|
Better development at grassroots
|
55
|
22.92
|
Reduction of bootlicking and lobbying in extension
agency
|
81
|
33.75
|
Affect employment pattern in extension
organization
|
27
|
11.25
|
Increased production among farmers
|
100
|
41.67
|
Specialized training will improve for farmers
|
211
|
87.92
|
Total
|
1888*
|
Source: Field Survey, 2010
*Multiple
responses recorded.
The opinions of the respondents as shown in Table 12 indicated that deregulating extension service delivery will improve specialized
training for fairness (87.92%), lead to most farmers not able to pay
for extension services (84.17%), cause the rate of adoption technologies
to reduce
(78.75%), but
cause the funding of extension service to be sustainable (72.08%). Others areas deregulation will
affect include; timeliness of extension
message (66.67%), improved commitment of extension agents (58.75%), and
improvement in extension agents discipline for service delivery (50.83%). However, the least area noted to be affected by deregulation
was in the area of better ward for extension agents performance (7.08).
4.4.7 Extension Services Farmers are willing to pay for
and amount
The extension services which the farmers are
willing to pay for and the amount involved were
identified. The result is presented in table 13.
Table 13: Distribution of Respondents Based on the Extension
Services they are
willing to pay for and mean amount
Extension
service/activities
|
Frequency
|
%
|
Mean
amount (
|
Participation in the establishment of
SPAT
|
108
|
45.00
|
3700
|
Mobilizing other farmers for group
message delivery at farmers cost
|
189
|
78.75
|
3400
|
Cost to arrange farm input supply
|
217
|
90.45
|
6450
|
Preparing schedule of farm activities
|
174
|
72.50
|
1250
|
Processing loan
|
200
|
83.33
|
8100
|
Allowance to EAs for home and farm
visits
|
201
|
83.75
|
4300
|
Helping with access to farm machinery
|
210
|
87.50
|
5100
|
Village accommodation for extension
agents
|
178
|
74.17
|
1400
|
Extension agents’ accommodation in the
nearest home
|
87
|
36.25
|
3100
|
Watching agricultural film show
|
150
|
62.50
|
500
|
Teaching new ideas in agriculture
|
185
|
77.08
|
4100
|
Supervising women activities
|
59
|
24.58
|
2700
|
Teaching how to keep record of farm
activity
|
122
|
50.83
|
1800
|
Provide meal subsidy for extension
agent
|
190
|
79.17
|
1000
|
Fuel extension agent car/motor bike
|
156
|
65.00
|
1050
|
Handbills, posters, leaflets that
contain valuable information on farm production
|
40
|
16.67
|
570
|
Giving advice on agricultural problems
|
153
|
63.75
|
5000
|
Support cost of farm radio programme
|
98
|
40.83
|
6100
|
Sources:
Field Survey, 2010
The results in Table 13 indicated that majority of the farmers were willing to pay for farm input supply (90.42%), access to farm machinery (87.50%), extension agents home and farm visits (83.75%), and processing
of agricultural loan (83.33%). Others include the provision of meal subsidy for extension
agents (79.17%), mobilizing other farmers for group message delivery at fanners cost (78.75%), teaching new
ideas in agriculture (77.50%). The least extension services the fanners
were willing to pay for were the provision of handbills, posters and leaflets
(16.67%). and payment for extension agents accommodation in the nearest town
(36.25%). In terms of the mean amount the
respondents were willing to pay, loan processing, farm input supply, support for farm radio
programme, advice on agricultural problems,
and access to farm machinery had the highest mean amount of N8100, N6450, N46100, N5000, and N45100, respectively. Watching agricultural film show had the least amount of N500, followed by handbills, posters and leaflets with N 570.00.
4.5 Effects
of Farmers Socio-Economic Characteristics on their Willingness to Pay for Extension Services
The
socio-economic determinants of farmers willingness to pay for extension services were estimated using the probit
multiple regression model. Table 14 shows the results of the analysis.
Table 14: Probit Multiple regression Results of Effect
of Farmers' Socio-Economic Characteristics on Willingness to pay for
Extension
Variable
|
Coefficient
(B)
|
SE
|
Wald
|
Sig.
|
Exp (B)
|
Sex
|
0.116
|
0.431
|
0.073
|
0.787
|
1.124
|
Age
|
-0.031**
|
0.025
|
1.967
|
0.111
|
0.969
|
Household size
|
-0.060
|
0.105
|
0.327
|
0.567
|
0.942
|
Education
|
0.017*
|
0.056
|
2.096
|
0.026
|
1.018
|
Farming experience
|
0.131*
|
0.024
|
2.669
|
0.016
|
1.134
|
Farm income
|
0.280*
|
0.781
|
5.129
|
0.006
|
1.324
|
Farm size
|
0.830*
|
0.391
|
4.513
|
0.034
|
2.293
|
Extension contact
|
0.251*
|
0.182
|
3.892
|
0.069
|
1.285
|
Constant
|
2.317*
|
1.228
|
3.560
|
0.059
|
0.099
|
-2 log likelihood =
151.953 **significant @ 10%
Cox and Snell R2 =
0.512 *Significant @ 5%
Chi-square = 30.965
Degree
of freedom (df) = 8
Significance (probability value) = 0.004
Source: Extracted
From Output of SPSS Computation.
From the results in Table 14,
the coefficient of multiple determination
i.e. Cox and Snell R2 was 0.512 or 51.2%. This indicates that about 51% of
the total variations in the dependent variable (i.e. willingness to pay for
extension services) were explained by the include independent variables. The chi-square value of 30.965 at df = 8 was significant at 5% level indicating that the model was a good fit. The results also showed that six (6) out of the eight (8) included variables were statistically significant with only the coefficient of age being significant at 10% level, and others at 5% level.
i.e. Cox and Snell R2 was 0.512 or 51.2%. This indicates that about 51% of
the total variations in the dependent variable (i.e. willingness to pay for
extension services) were explained by the include independent variables. The chi-square value of 30.965 at df = 8 was significant at 5% level indicating that the model was a good fit. The results also showed that six (6) out of the eight (8) included variables were statistically significant with only the coefficient of age being significant at 10% level, and others at 5% level.
All except the
coefficients of farmer's age and household size were positively signed. Thus,
an increase in these variables (educational level, farming
experience, farm income, farm size, and farmer's extension contact) will lead to increase in farmer's willingness to
pay for extension services. However, the older the farmer, the less
willing he or she to pay for extension services.
The coefficients of sex and farmer's household size were not statistically
significant.
4.6 Constraints to Farmer's
Willingness to Pay for Extension Services in
a Deregulated Economy
Factor analysis was used to identify constraints to farmers' willingness to pay for Extension Services in a deregulated economy.
Since
the purpose was to identify new factors, then the interpretation boils down to identifying the variables that load high for each factor. These variables loading high were used in naming each extracted factor. Kaiser (1958) developed a simple rule of thumb; that variables with coefficient of (0.30) of more have high loading and may be used in naming a factor. The result obtained using factor analysis is shown in Table 15.
the purpose was to identify new factors, then the interpretation boils down to identifying the variables that load high for each factor. These variables loading high were used in naming each extracted factor. Kaiser (1958) developed a simple rule of thumb; that variables with coefficient of (0.30) of more have high loading and may be used in naming a factor. The result obtained using factor analysis is shown in Table 15.
Table
15 Varimax Rotated Factor Matrix on
Constraints Limiting Farmers’ Willingness to pay for Extension Services in
the Study Area.
Variables
Code
|
Variables
Names
|
Factors
Financial Constraint
|
Factors
Social Constraint
|
Factors
Institutional Constraint
|
V01
|
Inadequate fund to pay for service
rendered
|
0.457
|
0.145
|
-0.134
|
V02
|
Most farmers will be reluctant to pay
for extension services
|
0.327
|
0.082
|
0.750
|
V03
|
High level of subsistence farming
|
0.279
|
0.640
|
0.000
|
V04
|
Exploitation by extension service
providers will be high
|
0.728
|
-0.092
|
-0.587
|
V05
|
Tendency of extension agents to focus
more on large-scale farmers to the determent of the small-scale famers
|
0.050
|
0.491
|
0.107
|
V06
|
Inadequate market to sell farm
surpluses as a result of improved extension service
|
0.190
|
0.8330
|
-0.516
|
V07
|
Difficult in attaching monetary value
to extension services
|
0.542
|
0.0252
|
-0.030
|
V08
|
Poor capacity building of extension
staff
|
0.215
|
0.139
|
0.926
|
V09
|
Irresponsive of extension services
providers to clientele needs
|
0.346
|
0.809
|
0.409
|
V010
|
Insufficient trained extension
personel
|
0.234
|
0.221
|
0.392
|
V011
|
Inadequate government guarantee,
regulations excesses and abuses
|
0.104
|
0.352
|
-0.216
|
Sources: Computed from field data, 2010.
Table 15 shows
that varimax rotated constraints militating against farmers’ willingness to pay
for extension services in the study area. From the data obtained, three major
constraints were extracted based on the responses of the respondents. These
were financial, social and institutional factors.
4.7 Hypothesis Testing
F- cal = 34.77 F-tab = 2.01
F - critical = Vi= N-K
- 240-8 = 232
V2 = K-1 8-1=7
at 0.05 level
F- cal (34.77) > F-tab (2.01). Therefore, the null hypothesis was
rejected
while the alternative hypothesis was accepted. This
implies that the socio-economic characteristics of the farmers had significant
effects on their willingness to pay for extension services in the study
area.
CHAPTER
FIVE
DISCUSSION
5.1 Socio-Economic Characteristics of Respondents
Table 1 indicates that males were more than the females. The
greater
number of males does not infer that they
out-number the females in the study area. Rather, it could mean that men
headed more farming households than the
women and thus, have more control over farm resources and the decision-making process of the households. This
finding collaborates the observations
of Bawa, D. B, Ani, A. O and Nuhu, H. S (2009), Edeh (2008), and Oladele and Obuh (2008) that males are mostly
the household heads who take major
decisions. Bawa et al (2009) further noted that the males are major decision takers when it comes to such issue
like privatization and adoption of
new technologies. In terms of age, the results show that the most
(48.33%) of the respondents were between 21 and 50 years of age, and a mean age of 49 years. Hence, the respondents
were still within the vibrant age class and still possess the strength for
farming and according to Bawa et al (2009), could be more disposed to extension
contact. Oladele (2008) also observed a mean age of 46 years for sampled
farmers in Oyo State in the study of
farmers' willingness to pay for extension services.
Majority (71%) of the respondents were married. This stems from the fact that all
the respondents were of marriage age. Though socially good, it has its negative
implication on the respondents' ability to fund extension services. Marriage
means more financial demand and this will compete with the limited financial resources available to the farmer to pay for
extension
services rendered.
The results also show that the respondents maintained a relatively large mean household size of 8 persons. This is in line with Daniela, J. H,
Smale, M, and Von Oppen, M. (2005) and Ezike (1999) which noted that the household size in southeast Nigeria
is large particularly in Ebonyi State. Based on the result in table 1, the
level of education of the fanners is
relatively low, as about 68% of the respondents had the first school
leaving certificate (primary education) as their highest academic qualification. This trend was also observed by
Edeh (2008) and Okoruwa, V. O, Ogundele O. O and Oyewusi, B. O (2006).
However, Ogunlade et al (2006) noted that about 59% of the respondents on the
potential of funding agricultural extension
operations by farmers in Kwara state, Nigeria had opportunity to acquire
formal education.
The low income
generated from farming may not assist farmers to pay or fund extension services
rendered to them. The dependence on personal saving
to fund farming activities implies that the respondents were not commercial-farming
oriented. Also, the high dependence on informal sources of funding indicates that the farmers are still operating at the
subsistence level. This source of funding is in conformity with Amalu (1998) which noted that the cheapest and safest
form of financing agricultural
production is personal or family saving where these are available.
Further, table 1 shows that the average farm size of the farmers was 0.9ha. This is
an indication of peasant level of farming among their respondents. Edeh (2008), Oladele (2008) and Idiong (2007) also noted
that farmers in Ebonyi, Oyo and
Cross River states operate on peasant level with an average farm size of 0.91ha, 4.0 ha and 0.42ha, respectively. Again,
the results show that the farmers
have long farming experience, having 31 years mean experience. This according to Clark and Akinbode (1968) can affect
and influence the rate of adoption of
new technology; and willingness to pay for
extension services (Oladele, 2008). The style of visitation of extension agents is not inconsonance with the practice of
Agricultural Development Programme (ADP) in Nigeria, which should be
fortnightly. However, the result
indicated that majority (74%) were visited once per month. This trend will unpair the monthly technical review meetings
(MTRM) of ADP. The tenurial system could
favour investment on land as majority of the respondents own their lands. This has a positive implication for funding
or willingness to pay for extension services by farmers. Farmers who own
their land will be more willing to pay for extension services that help improve
the productivity of their lands especially in the long-run.
5.2 Major
Packages/Technologies and Services Extended to Farmers by
Extension Agents
Results on Table 2 indicate that the most of the packages/technologies
extended to farmers were those associated with crops dominant in the study
area. As such, packages/technologies identified were those related to rice, cassava, maize and sweet potatoes. Ebonyi state is generally noted for
the production of these crops, especially rice. According to
Edeh (2008), rainfed lowlands (swamps) serve as a major source of
paddy production in Ebonyi state. Also, F.A.O. (2005) noted that rainfed
lowlands (fadama and flood plains) are the major source of rapid increase in
paddy production in recent years. The extension of NERICA upland rice
production technology as identified by 50% of the respondents shows that the
innovation is becoming widely accepted and appreciated by fanners.
Again, technologies associated
with mixed cropping was dominant, conforming with the farming systems prevalent among smallhodler farmers in
Nigeria. Mixed cropping
system helps to reduce the cost incurred
per crop as the cost is spread across crops cultivated per hectare at a
particular time. It also allows the farmer to efficiently utilize the limited
land resource available. These technologies associated with swamp and upland
rice and mixed cropping enterprises, especially cassava-maize-sweet potatoes
can be used to arouse the interest of fanners to fund agricultural technologies
for increased production.
Table 3 shows
that most identified extension services were those that bother on communicating
research findings to the farmers. This is expected because through agricultural extension services, dissemination of information on agricultural technologies and farmers'
capacity building are carried out
(Oladele, 2008). Srivastava and Jaffe (1992) noted that extension serves
as the link between farmers to transfer best practices from one farmer to another, to introduce or even enforce
agricultural policies and report farmers
problems back to research.
5.3 Trend in
Funding of Agricultural Extension Services in Ebonyi State Between 2000 and 2009
Results on Table 4 and figure 1A/1B show dwindling
funding of public agricultural
extension services in Ebonyi State. This implies that government is not stable
in the approval of budget estimate on agricultural extension service delivery
The unsteady budget estimate follows the pattern of funding of the Nigeria agricultural sector. The results collaborates the
finding of House Committee Policy
brief on Agriculture (2005), which noted that over the years the agricultural sector has suffered inadequate and unstable
funding from the government. It also opined that the patterns of agricultural sector funding hardly represent the best
and most effective use of public
resources. The dwindling trend could also be attributed to policy inconsistency of government, which has affected
the agricultural sector negatively. Researchers (Bell and Satau, 2009; Madukwe
and Eric, 1999) noted that Nigeria agricultural extension service has been
experiencing dwindling funding from the government in recent years. This
they observed, is very apparent in the sliding performances of the state wide
ADPs.
This again
reflects the budgetary allocations to the agricultural sector in the state and Nigeria in general. In the Maputo Declaration of
July 2003, a minimum of 10% budgetary
allocation to Agriculture was advocated to ensure adequate food security. However, House Committee Policy
brief on Agriculture (2005) showed
that the agricultural share of Ebonyi State budget was on average less than 10% minimum requirement. It noted
further that the highest percentage
share of the agricultural sector of 10.9% was recorded in 2004. This
trend has not changed significantly afterwards.
The
result obtained in Table 5 and Figures 2A/2B indicated
that the actual amount expended on agricultural public extension service is
grossly inadequate since the highest expenditure made on this area was about N99.5 million. According to Mathnmi et al., (2008), agricultural extension
service requires billions of naira for its operations.
Table
6 and Figure 3A/3B show that there is a great difference
between budget estimate and actual expenditure in agricultural extension
service delivery. It is quite disturbing and regrettable that government can
approve annual budget for Ministries, Departments and Agencies to carry out her policies and programs, and yet failed on the full implementation of budgets. This conforms to the work of Kali
(2010) who opined that over the years, budget implementation by the executive
arm of government at the local, state and federal levels has sabotaged key
public infrastructures. He further stated that it is very sad to note that no
state or federal administration in Nigeria have been able to achieve up to a
mere 45% annual budget implementation level in the last 12 years.
5.4 Farmers Willingness to Pay
for Extension Services Rendered by the ADP
The responses of the respondents as shown in Table 7 show that majority of them were not willing to pay for extension services, and
more males were in this category than the females.
Non-willingness of respondents
to pay for extension services may not be unconnected with their income levels, weak performance of ADP extension
service, and the peasant level of
their farm operations. These factors among others tend to limit farmers ability to fund or pay for technologies
and services rendered. Ali et al (2008) and Mwaura et al
(2010) showed that most reasons which farmers unwilling
to pay for extension services have indicated include inadequate income
and financial ability for this purpose; vague process of payment for extension services, small and fragmented land
holding. The findings however disagree with Bawa et al (2009)
which showed that 61% of the respondents in Adamawa State indicated their
readiness to pay for extension services is
presently not encouraged.
The relative increase in the percentage of fanners willing to pay for extension services in the future (Table 7) is a boost for extension privatization
in the study area. This opinion could be attributed to any future improvement in the farmers' income level and
scale of operation, and better performance
of the extension service. Again, 21 - 40% degree of willingness to pay shown by 50% of the respondents
is an indication of future success of
public funding of extension services in the area. However, Ali et al (2008) noted that farmers may
not pay this amount practically considering their conditions (Table 9).
Result obtained in Table 10 showed that the actual estimated amount
farmers were willing to pay for some selected extension services delivery dwindled over the years. This dwindling in the amount farmers were
willing to pay could be attributed to poor level of income of the farmers. Ali et
al (2008), Ahuja and Sen (2006) observed a positive and
significant effect of income on farmers' willingness to pay for extension
services.
The result
obtained in Table 11 and Figure 5A/5B revealed that the
amount expended by the government was
higher than that the farmers are willing to pay in all the years. This implies
that government should continue to
sponsor extension service delivery in the study area since the farmers
cannot afford the cost of the service. According to Bello et al (2009) majority of our farmers in Nigeria have weak
capital base to be able to pay fully for extension services.
Results on Table 12 show a general positive perception of the respondents on effects of deregulated economy on extension service delivery. This agrees with Bawa et al (2008) and Matanmi et al
(2008) who noted that most farmers agreed that privatization of ADP
extension services will have a positive impact of extension service delivery.
Respondents'
opinions may not be unconnected with the
successes recorded in Nigeria's telecommunication
industry which was privatized some years ago. Hence, if eventually the private sector participation in
extension services is increased, the programme will undoubtedly succeed. With
the observed results, it is obvious that public extension is not performing as
they should and there is need for
reform.
The willingness to pay values as presented in Table 13 indicate that farmers are more enthusiastic about extension services that tend to help
them improve on their income base such as access to farm
machinery, farm input supply, home and farm visit, and processing of loan. This
has implication for farmers' ability to pay since it is always limited by
income levels. Therefore,
policies that enhance the provision of these farm services is expected to increase the willingness to pay
values for extension services. Hence, this will enhance the funding of
extension services in a deregulated economy. In effect, it is pertinent
that some conditions which enhances the Income generating capacity of the
farmers be put in place before deregulation of extension services is embarked
upon. The low willingness to pay values for such extension services as
participation in the establishment SPAT; scheduling of farm activities,
providing of accommodation for extension agents, teaching of how to keep farm
record; providing meal subsidy for extension agents among others, indicate that
extension efforts should target farmers as groups rather than individuals.
This, according to Daniela et al (2005) provides incentives for private
participation in extension service delivery.
5.5
Effects of Farmers' Socio-Economic Characteristics on their Willingness to Pay
for Extension Services
Results
presented on Table 14 indicate that respondents’ age had a negative and
significant effect on willingness to pay for extension services. This implies
that the older the farmer, the less willing to pay for extension services. The
young people are willing to pay because they are ready to adopt new
technologies that are provided in the extension services to improve their
agricultural practices. According to Chebil et al (2009) age of famer is
important in the utilization, adoption and willingness to pay for the service.
The eagerness for information coupled with the socio-economic characteristics
of the young farmers increase their probability to demand and pay for extension
services either on crop or animal husbandry (Kaliba et at, 2007;
Oladele, 2008; Muwamra et al9 2010). Similar negative and significant relationship exists between farmers' household size and their willingness to pay for
extension services. Large households
tend to spend large proportion of their income on household food consumption with less to invest in such
activities as extension services. The observation
deviates from the finding of Oladele (2008) which noted a positive and non-significant relationship between
household size and farmers
willingness to pay for extension services.
Farmers'
educational level has positive effect on their eagerness to adopt technologies and willingness to pay for
extension services. Hence, the more
educated the farmers are, the higher their willingness to pay for extension services. Researchers (Daniela et al,
2005; Ogunlade, 2006, Oladele, 2008)
showed similar result of a positive and significant effect of education on farmers willingness and ability to
pay for extension services. Educated
farmers can assimilate information and covert it into knowledge more
effectively than farmers with limited education. Also, the more educated
people are, the more enlightened they are about the importance of the extension services unlike the people with
little formal education. Further,
the significant positive influence of farming experience on farmers' willingness
to pay indicates that more experienced farmers are more willing to pay
for extension services than those in the farming business for just few years. According to Daniela et al (2005) the
extent of farming experience
generates relevant knowledge, which
increases farmers' willingness to pay for
extension services.
The effect of farm income on farmers' willingness to pay for extension
services corroborates the findings of Oladele (2008), Ali et al (2008), Ahuja and Sen (2006) which observed a
positive and significant effect of
income on farmers willingness to pay for extension services. Households at higher income levels are more
willing to pay for extension services. This is because the household
will have more financial resources to take care of family needs and also pay
for extension service. Forti et al (2007) also shwoed that farmers income among
others significantly affect the demand for private fee-for-service extension in
Zimbabew. The result also indicated that farm
size has a positive and statistically significant influence on farmers’ willingness to pay for
extension services. Thus, farmers
with large farm sizes have greater probability to fund extension services
in a deregulated economy. This is because farmers with large farm sizes tend to be commercial oriented, and this
could lead to higher production and
profit. This result supports the views of Oladele (2008), Ogunlade
(2006) and Yapa and Ariyawaradana (2005). The frequency of extension contacts the farmers had positively
influenced their willingness to pay
for extension services. Frequent extension contact with farmers increases
their level of technology awareness and utilization, and this tend to influence farmers demand for extension services
positively. Hence, a well-informed
farmer through adequnte extension contacts may tend to be more willing to fund/pay for extension services than
those who rarely have extension contact. Farmers may be desirous of
adopting new practices but may be
constrained by inadequate information about that particular innovation, which may in part be caused by the
inability of the extension personnel
to reach the fanners (Ani et at, 2004). Apantaku and Fakoya (2000) also showed that length of contact with
extension agents significantly correlates with farmers willingness to
contribute fund for extension services.
A test of the synergistic effect of farmers5 socio-economic characteristics
on willingness to pay for extension services was done using the chi-square
test. The chi-square value was 30.965 and probability value of 0.004 indicating that it is significant 5%
level. Thus, the null (Ho)
hypothesis was
rejected and it was concluded that the farmers socio-economic
characteristics have significant effect on their willingness to pay for
extension services in the study area.
5.6 Constraints
against Farmers Willingness to Pay for Extension
Services in a Deregulated Economy
Constraints are critical to the success of extension service delivery in
a deregulated economy. The result of factor analysis
extracted three (3) major constraints limiting farmers' willingness to pay
for extension service in the study area as shown in Table 15. Based on the
responses of the respondents,
only variables with constraint loadings of 0.30 and above at 10% overlapping variance were used in naming the
constraints. (Ashley, et al;
2006; Madukwe, 2004).Variables
that loaded in more than one constraints as in the case of variable 9 was discarded; while variables that have constraints
loading of less than 0.30 were used. The next thing to do as reported by Kessler 2006 was giving each
constraint a denomination that best
describes or characterizes the set of variables contained in the constraints. In this regard, the variables were
grouped into three (3) major constraints
as: Constraint l (Financial constraint), Constraint 2 (Social constraint),
and Constraint 3 (Institutional Constraint).
Under constraint
1 (Financial constraint), the specific constraining variables against farmers'
willingness to pay for extension services were: inadequate fund to pay for the services rendered (Voi = 0.4), most
farmers will be reluctant to pay for extension services (V02
= 0.3), exploitation by extension service
providers will be high (V04 = 0.7), and difficulty in attaching
monetary value to extension services (V07 = 0.5).All these factors are related
to financial issue. Thus, it was named financial constraint. These agrees with the findings of Bello and Salau (2009)
and Chukwuone et al (2006) who
opined that inadequate fund to pay for extension services rendered by extension agents are major constraint
to effective privatization and commercialization of extension services
in Nigeria.
After careful examination, factor 2 was named Social constraint. This is
because the variables that loaded high under this factor are related mostly to social
problems that would likely occur due to deregulation. They include: High level of subsistence farming (V03 = 0.6),
tendency of extension agent to focus
more on large scale fanners to the detriment of the small scale farmers (V05 = 0.4), Inadequate market to sell farm
surplus as a result of improved
extension services (V06 = 0.8) and inadequate government quarantees, regulation and control over extension
providers' excesses and abuses (Vol
11= 0.3).
However, factor 3 (three) was named institutional constraint after critical
observation. This is because the factors that loaded high under this constraint related mostly to the problems that
would affect extension institutions.
These include: poor capacity building of extension staff (V08 = 0.9), irresponsiveness of the extension
service providers to clientele needs
(V09 = 0.4) and insufficient trained extension personnel (V010 = 0.3).
All these
constraints were equally identified by Ajieh et al (2008), and Rivera
and Gary (2007).They noted that client needs which are not likely to yield profit may be excluded from services to be
provided by extensionists in a
deregulated economy. Furthermore, Chukwuone et al (2006), and
Rivera and Gary
(2007) opined that the most obvious short coming in
Extension services
privatization and commercialization is difficulty of collecting users fees and establishing cost accounting procedure to set charges at appropriate levels. Thus, financial, social and institutional constraints limit farmers' willingness to pay for extension services in
the study area.
SUMMARY,
CONCLUSION AND RECOMMENDATIONS
6.1 Summary
In this study, it was discovered that:
(i)
Majority of the households were headed by the males, with
a mean age of 49 years and maintained a relatively large
household size of eight (8) persons
(ii)
Educational level
was low, and farmers operate at the subsistence level with
an average farm holding of 0.9ha and personal savings as major source of farm finance.
(iii)
Government actual release of fund for ADP extension
services dwindled throughout the period with peak of about N 99.5 million in 2004 and lowest of about N39.8 million in 2002.
(iv)
A great
difference was observed between the budget estimates and the actual expenditure
on agricultural extension service
(v)
Majority
of the respondents were not willing to pay/fund extension services while a high proportion of those willing
to pay in future indicated 21- 40%
degree of willingness to pay.
(vi)
There was a significant difference between the actual
amount the farmers'
were willing to pay and the amount expended by the government in most of the years in agricultural extension
service delivery in the study area.
(vii)
Main
effects of deregulation on extension services were probability of specialized training for farmers to improve; and
tendency of most farmers not to be
able to afford payment for extension services.
(viii)
High
proportion of the respondents were willing to pay for cost of arranging for input supply; cost of access to farm
machinery; extension agents' home and
farm visits; and cost of processing loans.
(ix)
Highest willingness
to pay values of N8100, N6450 and N6100 were recorded for loan processing, cost to arrange farm
input supply, and support for farm radio programme,
respectively.
(x)
Educational
level, farming experience, farm income, farm size and frequency of extension contact had significantly positive effect on farmer's willingness to pay while age and
household size had significant
negative effect on it.
(xi)
Major constraints against farmers' willingness to pay for
extension services in a deregulated economy were: financial, social
and institutional constraints.
6.2
Conclusion
According to the results of the study, it can be concluded that a major proportion of the farmers did not express high level of willingness to pay/fund agricultural extension services. It seems the farmers who
found extension services useful to their production have not
caught the vision of personal contributions to make the agricultural
extension programme sustainable. The existing low willingness to fund
extension services in the area is not unconnected with the farmers' poor
economic and educational backgrounds, and subsistence level of
farming.
6.3
Recommendations
Based on the research findings, the following recommendations were made:
(i)
The extension -agency of the state should educate farmers
on cost
of its operations and the need for their
contribution.
(ii)
Farmers with large farms and at least post secondary
education could be the initial target for supports, while the
farmer associations should be an avenue for effective education.
(iii)
Extension services should be backed up with interest
free loans, and supply of inputs to farmers at subsidized rate. The
production of farmers can be monitored for between five (5) and ten
(10) years and
When the farmers are sufficiently and economically empowered, commercialization of extension services can be
introduced.
(iv)
The
commercialization and privatization of agricultural extension services should be gradual process and in phases.
First, government should
commercialize extension services but retain partial privatization and monitoring of the services
bearing in mind the food production
inadequacies in Nigeria. It is therefore important that a workable fashion for the implementation of the
policy is designed for the expected
impact of improving extension services and farmers' productivity.
(v)
The country's educational system should be substantially
improved to raise the literacy level with the view to eliminating
obstacle in the development of the poor who are mainly fanners.
6.4
Recommendation for Further Research
Future research should be focused on the comparative study of farmers and extension agents’ perception of funding
agricultural extension services in a
deregulated economy. Also, research should be done on the impact of budgetary allocations on agricultural extension
service delivery in the study area.
REFERENCES
Afolabi, O. 2003, Effect of Deregulation should precede
privatization. Guardian Newspaper, March, 2003.
15(16, 632), 28 - 29.
Agboti,
O. 2004. Deregulation is the Answer. Nigerian Patriot Newspaper. March,
2004. 10(78). 3-4.
Agumagu, A. C. 2001. Privatization, Commercialization and
Sustainable Agricultural Extension in Nigeria: Issues at Stake. Privatization
and Commercialization of Agricultural Extension Services
Delivery in Nigeria: Prospects and Problems. P. 119.
Ahuja, V. and Sen, A. 2006. Willingness to Pay for
Veterinary Services; Evidence
from Poor Areas in Rural India. Pro-Poor Livestock Policy Initiative Research Report (Online:www).
Ajieh, P.C., Agwu, A.E. and Anyanwu, A.C. 2008.
Constraints to Privatization and Commercialization of Agricultural
Extension Services as Perceived by Extension Professionals and
Farmers. African Journal of Agricultural Research. Vol.3 (5);343 - 347.
Alfred, S.D.Y. and Adepoju, A.A. 2006. Fanners' Perception
of Agricultural Privatization on cocoa Production in Ondo
State, Nigeria. Proceedings of 11th Annual
Conference of Agricultural Extension Society
of Nigeria (AESON), University of Agriculture, Abeokuta, Ogun State. April 3 -6, 2006.
Ali, S., Morteza, A., Hossain, S.F. and Amir, A. 2008. An
Assessment of '. Farmers Willingness to Pay for Wheat Consultant
Engineers Project in Iran. American Journal of Agricultural and
Biological Sciences. Vol 3(4): 706 -711.
Amalu, U.C. 1998. Agricultural Research and Extension
Delivery System in Sub-saharan Africa. The University of Calabar Press,
Calabar, Nigeria.
Anderson, R.J. and Feder, G. 2003. Rural Extension
Services:
Agriculture and Rural Development. (On-line:http://econ.worldbank.org/ external/default/main? pagePK = 64165259 & the SitePk - 469382 & piPk -64165421 & menu Pk= 64166093 & entity ID - 000094946-03031111352821).
Agriculture and Rural Development. (On-line:http://econ.worldbank.org/ external/default/main? pagePK = 64165259 & the SitePk - 469382 & piPk -64165421 & menu Pk= 64166093 & entity ID - 000094946-03031111352821).
Ani, A.O., Ogunnika, O. and Ifah, S.S. 2004.
Relationship Between Socio-Characteristics of Rural Women
Farmers and their Adoption of Farm Technologies in Southern
Ebonyi State, Nigeria. International Journal of Agriculture and Biology. Vol. 6(5); 802 -805.
Apantaku, S.O. and Fakoya, E.G. 2000. Influence of
Community Based Associations in Promoting Community Development in Rural Areas of
South Western Nigeria. Journal of Extension System. Vol 16/.47-60.
Aurelia, G. M. 1999. Prolitics of Economics Reforms in
Japan. Collected Papers: The Politics of
Deregulation and Japanese Agriculture, tittp-//www.free.defmition.com/Deregulation.html (22/05/2005).
Bawa, D.B., Ani, A.O. and Nuhu, H.S. 2009. Perception of
Privatization and Commercialization of Agricultural Extension Services in Adamawa State, Nigeria. American-Eurasian. Journal of Sustainable Agriculture, Vol3(3):375-380.
Bello, M and E. S Salua (2009).A case for Participatory
(Cost Sharing) Approach to Agricultural Extension Delivery in Nigeria. Journal
of Agricultural Extension vol 13 (1) P. 85.
Bellow, M. and Salau, E.S. 2009. A Case for Participatory
(Cost sharing) Approach to Agricultural Extension Delivery in
Nigeria. Journal of Agricultural Extension, Vol 13 (1): 84-94.
Chebil, A., Nair, H. and Zaibet, L. 2009. Factors
Affecting Farmers Willingness
to Adopt Salt-Tolerant Forage Crops in South-Eastern Tunisia. African Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics. Vol
3(1): 19-27.
Chukwu,
U.C. 2003. Accounting and Finance Terminologies. Cheston Publishers Ltd. Enugu. P. 26.
Chukwuone,
N.A., Agwu, A.E. and Ozor, N. 2006. Constraints and Strategies Towards Effective Cost-sharing of Agricultural Technology
Delivery in Nigeria: Perception of Farmers and Agricultural Extension
Personnel, Journal of International Agricultural
and Extension Education. Vol.
13(1): 1 - 13.
Clark, R.C. and Akinbode, L.A. 1968, Factors Associated
with Adoption of Three Farm Practices in the Western State of Nigeria. Research
Bulletin 1, Faculty of
Agriculture, University of Ife, Ile-lfe, Nigeria.
Daniela, J.H., Smale, M., and Von Oppen, M. 2005.
Private Participation in Agricultural Extension in Nigeria and Benin: Determining the Willingness to Pay for Information. Selected Paper 136774 Prepared for Presentation at the American Agricultural Economics
Association Annual Meeting, Providence, Rhode
Island, July 24 - 27, 2005.
Dimaelu, M.U. and Madukwe, M.C. 2001. Extension Workers'
Perception of Privatization and Communication of Extension Services in
Enugu State, Nigeria. Privatization and Communication of
Agricultural Extension Services delivery in Nigeria: Prospects and
Problems, P. 34.
EBADEP, 2001. Annual Report. Annex, S.ii.
EBADEP, 2003. The 2003 - 2005 National Rolling Plan,
and the 2003 Budget.
EBADEP, 2004. The 2004 - 2009 National Roiling Plan!
Capital Budget. Annex, S. Vii.
EBMOI (Ebonyi State Ministry of Information). 2005.Diary.
A Publication of the Ministry of Information, Abakaliki,
Ebonyi State, Nigeria,
Edeh, H.O. 2008. Analysis of Environmental Risk Factors
Affecting Rice Farming in Ebonyi State, Nigeria. M.Sc Thesis Submitted
to the Department
of Agricultural Economics, University of Nigeria, Nsukka.
Ekpe,1.1., Okpone, E.G., Ogbodo, E.N. and Nwite, J.N.
2005. Physico-chemical Properties of Four Ultisols under Different
Vegetation cover in
South-Eastern Nigeria. Journal of Science of Agriculture, Food Technology and Environment. Vol 5:74 - 78.
Eziakor, I.G. and Isitor, S.U. 1997. Financing Technology
Adoption in Nigeria; The Role of a Development Bank Towards the
Survival of Agricultural Extension System in Nigeria. P 7,
Ezike, K.N.N. 1999. Determinants of Borrowing and Saving
Capacity of Smallholder Farmers in South Eastern Nigeria. Ph.D Thesis submitted
to the Department of Agricultural Economics and
Extension, Enugu State University of Science and Technology (ESUT) Enugu.
FAO.
(Food and Agricultural Organisation). 2005. Nigeria: Latest F.A.O. Statistics.
(On-line:www.riceweb.org/countires/Nigeria,htw.)
Forti, R., Nyakudya, I., Moyo. M., Chikuvire, J. and
Mlambo, N. 2007. Determinants of Fanner Demand for
"Fee-for-Service" Extension in Zimbabwe: The Case of Mashoinaland
Central Province. Journal of International Agricultural and Extension Education. Vol.14 (1):95 -104.
Gbenga O. 1998. Contribution Towards Agricultural
Development: The Experience of World Bank in Nigeria. Nigerian Agriculture
and the World Bank. A partnership for
Development ARMTI (c). P.8.
Hansra, B.S. and Adhiguru, P. 1998.
Agriculture Transfer of Technology Approaches
since Independence. India Journal of Extension Education. Vol 9:2168-2176.
Herbert. W. E. 1999. Some Perspectives on the Structural Analysis
of Deregulation/Privatization.
Nigeria Financial Review, 3(5).INFODATA Ltd.
Lagos.
House Committee Policy Brief (2005). Sustainable
Funding of Agricultural Sector inNigeria.(On-line:http://www.pak-nigeria.org/pdfs/14_AgPolicy_Brief_2-2 Funding.pdf).
Idiong, I.C. 2007. Estimation of Farm
Level Technical Efficiency in Small-scale
swamp Rice Production in Cross River State of Nigeria: A
Stochastic
Frontier Approach. World Journal of Agricultural Sciences. 3(5):653-658.
IFAD, 1999. Nigerian Root and Tuber Expansion
Programme Appraisal Report .EBADEP. P.4.
Ikhide, S. L 1990. Deregulation: Part of Structural
Adjustment Programme. Nigeria Financial Review INODATA Ltd, Lagos. 6(3).
Kaiser, 1. (1958) Quoted by Madukwe M. C. in Factor Analysis and Applications. Mimeographed
UNN,1996.
Kali Gwagwa (2010). “Improved
Budget Implementation: Key to Nigeria’s Recovery”. Retrieved from
www.focusnigeria.com.
Kaliba, A.R.,
Featherstone, A.M. and Norman, D.W. 1997. A Stall-Feeding
Management for
Improved Cattle in Seminal Central Tanzania: Factors
Influencing Adoption. Agricultural Economics. 17:133 -146.
La-Anyame, S. 1998. The Agricultural Industry in West
Africa. Ghana University Press, Accra. P. 70.
Liot, C.A., 1998. Agricultural Credit Administration by
Commercial Banks: The United bank; for Africa Experience in Okorie,
A. and Ijere M.O. Reading in Agricultural Finance. Longman
(Nig.) Pic. Lagos.
Madu, O. 2003. Deregulation of Telecom. Sector Fetches
Government N130 billion. Guardian Newspaper. May, 2003, 17(.16, 720), 37
- 38.
Madukwe, M, C. and Eric, A.P. 1999. Privatization and
Commercialization of Extension Service in Nigeria: Prospects and Challenges.
Proceedings of the 5th Annual National Conference of Agricultural Extension Society of Nigeria. AESON. P.9.
Maputo Declaration on Agriculture and
Food Security in Africa. 2003.(On-line:http://www.acpsec.org/summits/Maputo/Maputo
declaration eruhtml).
Matanmi, B.M., Adesiji, G.B. and
Omokore, D.F. 2008. Need for Privatization
of Agricultural Extension Services in Nigeria. Global Approaches to Extension Practice. Vol 4(2):61 - 64.
Mwaura, F., Muwanika, F.R. and Okoboi, G. 2010.
Willingness to Pay for
Extension Services in Uganda Among Farmers Involved in Crop and Animal Husbandry. Contributed Paper Presented at the Joint
3r African Association of Agricultural Economists (A/IE) and 48*' Agricultural Economists Association of
South Africa (AEASA) Conference, Cape Town, South Africa, 19-23 September, 2010.
NO A. 2003. Growing the Private Sector/Implementing a
Social Charter. Nigeria: National Economic Empowerment and Development
Strategy (NEEDS). Produced by
National Orientation Agency, Headquarters, Abuja. Pp. 5-6.
NPC (National Population Commission) 2006. Population
Census, (Online: www .population.gov .ng/ftles/nationa.pdf).
Odili, M.A.C.A. 2001, Problems and Prospects of
Privatization of Public Enterprises in Nigeria. Privatization and
Commercialization of Agricultural Extension
Services Delivery in Nigeria: Prospects and Problems. ARSON. P.27. 13.
Ogunlade,
1., Adekunle, O.A. and Akangbe, J.A. 2006. Perceived Usefulness and Potential of Funding Agricultural Extension Operation
by Farmers, in Kwara State, Nigeria. International Journal of Agriculture and Biology.
Vol. 8(3): 402-405.
Okoruwa, V.O., Ogundele, O.O, and Oyewusi, B.O. 2000.
Efficiency and Productivity of Farmers in Nigeria: A Study of Rice Farmers
in North Central Nigeria, Poster Paper Prepared for Presentation at
the International
Association of Agricultural Economists Conference, Gold Coast, Australia, 12-18 August, 2006.
Oladele, O.I. 2008. Factors Determining Farmers'
Willingness to Pay for Extension Services in Oyo State, Nigeria. Agricultura
Tropica et subtropica. Vol41(l):165 - 170.
Oladele, O.I. and Obuh, J. 2008. Perceived Effect of
Privatization of Extension Services Among Researchers Extension Agents and Farmers in Oyo State, Nigeria. Agricultural Journal. Vol 3(5):4Q9-413.
Orolugbagbe, I. 2004. Effect of Deregulation should precede
Privatization. Vanguard Newspaper, March, 2004,
14(20,125). 43 - 44.
Oyedokun, A. O. 2001/Collaboration of Scientists in
Agricultural Research Institute of Nigeria: Implication for
Privatization and Commercialization of Agricultural Extension. Journal
of Agricultural Extension. AESON. 5(31).
Philip,
E.F, and Carl, S.W. 1984. Accounting Principle Von. Hoffmann Press. New York. P.85.
Rivera, W.M. and Cary, J.W. 1997. Privatizing
Agricultural Extension. In: B.E. Swanson, R,P. Bentz and A.I. Sofranko (eds.) Improving Agricultural Extension - A Reference Manual, Rome; FAG: Pp 203 -211.
Srivastava, J. and Jaffee, S. 1992. Seed Systems
Development, the Appropriate Roles of Public and Private Sectors. World
Bank Discussion Paper No. 167, World
Bank, Washington, D.C.
Tunde, R. 1998. The Food Problem in Nigeria: A challenge
for the Agricultural Sector. The Nigerian Journal of
Agricultural and Rural Management, Vol 2(10): 51 - 65.
Umali, D.I,, and Schwartz, L. 1994. Public and Private
Agricultural Extension: Beyond Traditional Frontiers. World Bank Discussion Papers, No.236. Washington, D.C. (On-line:www.landfood.
unimelb. edu.au/ dean/falveybk/refs.html).
Umeabali, E.E. 2003. The Role of Agricultural Extension
Education in Poverty Alleviation; Lessons from the study of Agric
Extension in Ohaji/Egbema Local Government Council of Imo Stale. The Nigeria Journal of Agricultural and Rural Management.
6(2). 1.
Umeh, G. N. 2003. Lecture Note on
Agricultural Extension Administration. Unpublished.
EBSU.
Yapa, K.D.AJ. arid Ariyawardana, A.
2005. Willingness to pay for Fee-Based
Extension Services by the smallhodlers in GaleDistrict
Online:www.sIjol.info/index.php/SJAE/ArticIe/view/l 824/1517).
Department of
Agricultural Economics
Extension & Management
Ebonyi State
University, Abakaliki.
Dear Respondents,
The student is conducting a research titled: Funding Ebonyi State Agricultural Public Extension
Service in Deregulated
Economy.
Please, your
assistance is highly needed in supplying appropriate information to the questionnaire. Any information given will be utilized
only for the research, and will be treated as confidential, and your name will
not be reflected in the field report. So, feel free to supply
all the required information.
Sincerely, thanks for your anticipated co-operation.
QUESTIONNAIRE
Section
A: Socio-Economic Characteristics of Respondents please tick (√) where
appropriate
1.
Sex: (i)
Male (ii) Female
2.
Age (years):
(i) 21-30 (ii) 31-40 (iii)
41-50 (iv) 51-60
(v) 61-70 (vi) 71-80 (vii) 81-90 (viii) 91-100
3.
Marital
Status: (i) Single (ii) Married (iii) Widow/widower
(iv) Divorced
4.
Household
Size: (i) 1-3 (ii) 4-6 (iii)
7-9 (iv) 10 - 12
5.
Educational Level: (i)
No Formal Education (ii)
Primary Education
(iii) Secondary Education (iv) Tertiary (OND HND, First degree
etc)
6.
Annual
Farm income:
(i) N21,000 – N40,000 (ii) N41,000 – N60,000
(iii) N61,000 – N70,000 (iv)
N71,000 – N80,000
(v) N81,000 – N90,000 (vi)
91,000 – N100,00
7.
What
is your major source of funding for farming?
(i) Personal
savings (ii) Information Loan (iii)
Bank (iv) Grant (v) Gift
8.
How
many hectares of farmland do you cultivate yearly?
(i) 0.1 – 0.5 (ii) 0.6 – 1.0 (iii) 1.1 – 1.5
(iv) 1.6 – 20 (v) 2.1 -2.5 (vi)
9.
How
long have you been in farming?
(i) 1 -10 year (ii)
11 -20 (iii) 21 - 30
(iv) 31 -40
years
(v) 41 -50
(vi) 51 - 60
10. How often do
extension agents come to you?
(i) Once in 2
weeks (ii)
Once in 4 weeks
(iii) Once in 8
weeks
11. How do you
acquire your farmland?
(i) my own (ii)
Rental
Section B: Major Packages/Technologies
and Services Extended to Farmers by Extension Agents
12. Which of these
technologies have been extended to you by extension agents?
(i) Dry season
vegetable production (exotic vegetable production, mulching, using organic
manure and correct spacing)
(ii)
Yam/maize/vegetable (Rapid seed yam multiplication, improved maixe varieties,
spacing and fertilizer application)
(iii)
Cassava/maize/sweet potatoes (use of improved varieties of cassava maize and
sweet potato, and soil enrichment with potato)
(vi)
Late
maize/melon (Row planting, spacing, improved varities and fertilizer
application)
(vii)
Swamp
rice production (improved varieties, early planting, line, planting and pest
disease control in rice field with emphasis on African Rice. Gall midge
(viii)
Processing
cassava/sweet potato into flour (peeling, wasting, grating, drying, milling,
and sieving)
(ix)
Utilization
of cassava/sweet potato flour (measuring ingredients, mixing, etc)
(x)
Production
of fruit juices, processing and utilization of soyabean (selection, washing,
blending, sieving, cooling and storage)
13. Which of these
services have been rendered to you by ADP/extension agents?
(i)
Establishment
of small plot adoption technique (SPAT)
(ii) Formation of
women groups
(iii)
Providing
information to women farmers
(iv)
Identify
rural problems
(v) Getting me involved in non-farm activities
(vi)
Supervising
our women activities
(vii)
Assisted
to arrange input supply to me
(viii)Helped me to
prepare schedule of farm activities
(ix)
Assisted
me in process loan
(x)
Initiated
and promoted leadership among dewellers
(xi)
Helped
source market for my farm products
(xii)
Assisted
in organizing our group meetings
(xiii)Organized shows
for us
(xiv)
Communicate
recommended practices to us
(xv)
Taught
me new ideas in agriculture
(xvi)
Taught
me how to keep of any farm activity
(xvii)
Gave
me advice on how to handle my agricultural problems
(xviii)
Paid
visits to my home and farms to assist me
(xix)
Helped
me to access farm machinery
Section C: Farmers willingness to pay for Extension
Service Rendered by the ADP
Preamble: funding has been identified as a major
problems to EBADEP in its quest to deliver efficient and effective extension
services to you. With adequate fund, it is expected that EBADEP will be highly
efficient like most privatized establishments in delivering its services to
you. However, to achieve this, EBADEP is proposing that its service recipients will
pay some fees for services rendered.
14. Are you willing to pay any extension services
rendered to you by EBADEP?
(i) Yes (ii) No
15. If you are not
willing now, will you pay in the future? (i) Yes (ii) No
16. If yes, please
indicate you percentage of willingness to pay for any service?